WO2004109566A1 - Conditional rate modelling - Google Patents

Conditional rate modelling Download PDF

Info

Publication number
WO2004109566A1
WO2004109566A1 PCT/AU2004/000770 AU2004000770W WO2004109566A1 WO 2004109566 A1 WO2004109566 A1 WO 2004109566A1 AU 2004000770 W AU2004000770 W AU 2004000770W WO 2004109566 A1 WO2004109566 A1 WO 2004109566A1
Authority
WO
WIPO (PCT)
Prior art keywords
rate
specified
zero coupon
series
issuers
Prior art date
Application number
PCT/AU2004/000770
Other languages
French (fr)
Inventor
Andrew Cumming
Original Assignee
Andrew Cumming
Priority date (The priority date is an assumption and is not a legal conclusion. Google has not performed a legal analysis and makes no representation as to the accuracy of the date listed.)
Filing date
Publication date
Application filed by Andrew Cumming filed Critical Andrew Cumming
Priority to AU2004246035A priority Critical patent/AU2004246035C1/en
Priority to GB0600407A priority patent/GB2419204A/en
Publication of WO2004109566A1 publication Critical patent/WO2004109566A1/en
Priority to US11/297,476 priority patent/US7979330B2/en

Links

Classifications

    • GPHYSICS
    • G06COMPUTING; CALCULATING OR COUNTING
    • G06QINFORMATION AND COMMUNICATION TECHNOLOGY [ICT] SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES; SYSTEMS OR METHODS SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES, NOT OTHERWISE PROVIDED FOR
    • G06Q40/00Finance; Insurance; Tax strategies; Processing of corporate or income taxes
    • G06Q40/04Trading; Exchange, e.g. stocks, commodities, derivatives or currency exchange
    • GPHYSICS
    • G06COMPUTING; CALCULATING OR COUNTING
    • G06FELECTRIC DIGITAL DATA PROCESSING
    • G06F17/00Digital computing or data processing equipment or methods, specially adapted for specific functions
    • G06F17/10Complex mathematical operations
    • G06F17/18Complex mathematical operations for evaluating statistical data, e.g. average values, frequency distributions, probability functions, regression analysis
    • GPHYSICS
    • G06COMPUTING; CALCULATING OR COUNTING
    • G06QINFORMATION AND COMMUNICATION TECHNOLOGY [ICT] SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES; SYSTEMS OR METHODS SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES, NOT OTHERWISE PROVIDED FOR
    • G06Q40/00Finance; Insurance; Tax strategies; Processing of corporate or income taxes
    • GPHYSICS
    • G06COMPUTING; CALCULATING OR COUNTING
    • G06QINFORMATION AND COMMUNICATION TECHNOLOGY [ICT] SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES; SYSTEMS OR METHODS SPECIALLY ADAPTED FOR ADMINISTRATIVE, COMMERCIAL, FINANCIAL, MANAGERIAL OR SUPERVISORY PURPOSES, NOT OTHERWISE PROVIDED FOR
    • G06Q40/00Finance; Insurance; Tax strategies; Processing of corporate or income taxes
    • G06Q40/06Asset management; Financial planning or analysis

Definitions

  • the invention relates to conditional rate modelling and, in particular, to modelling unknown values of several rate series at specified times.
  • This invention has been developed primarily for use in modelling the zero coupon rate curves of several bond issuers given limited trading data and will be described hereinafter with reference to this application. However, it will be appreciated that the invention is not limited to that particular field of use.
  • a valuation model typically takes as input the current values of a number of market rates and gives as output a theoretical price, or fair value, of the instrument in question. This allows the valuation of a financial instrument that may not have traded recently, provided that the input market rates are available.
  • a basic use of valuation models is to determine the daily profit and loss of trading portfolios. This involves comparing the value of a trading portfolio at the end of one trading day with its value at the end of the previous trading day, and requires the valuation of financial instruments that may not have traded in the course of the trading day. Valuation models are also used to inform trading decisions and to assess the risks arising out of trading portfolios.
  • Market risk is the risk of the value of a trading portfolio decreasing.
  • Credit risk is the risk of the counter-parties of trades defaulting on their contractual obligations. The amount of loss attributable to a default depends, at least in part, on the market value of the trades of the defaulting counter-party at the time of default.
  • the analysis of market risk involves making probabilistic assumptions about how market rates may change in the future. The impact of possible market rate changes on the value of a trading portfolio is then quantified and various measures of risk can be calculated.
  • a common method of market risk assessment is historical simulation. Historically observed rate changes of several rate series together are assumed to be statistically independent and to form a representative random sample and are applied to current rates. The resulting sets of rates (one for each historical time interval) are then used to revalue an existing trading portfolio. This gives a set of hypothetical future portfolio values used to calculate measures of market risk arising out of the trading portfolio.
  • this method disadvantageously requires gaps in the historical rate series to have been filled before the analysis begins. It also assumes that a complete set of current rates exists.
  • One known approach is to set each unknown rate to its previous known value. This can cause long sequences of repeated values, which leads to underestimation of risk, and sudden large jumps to the next known value, which leads to overestimation of risk.
  • Another approach is to fill gaps in each rate series by linearly interpolating between the known rates. This involves graphing, for each rate series, the known values, drawing straight lines between successive known values and reading off the unknown rates from the resulting graph. This approach tends to cause underestimation of risk because it ignores the inherent variation in rates and does not take into account the fact that the rate series are correlated.
  • a significant disadvantage of prior art methods of modelling unknown rates is that they do not take account of all the known rates, including those of other rate series and those known at other times, that are related to the unknown rates. The effect of this is inaccuracy in any pricing or analysis of risk that depends on such rates.
  • a computer-implemented method of modelling unknown values of several rate series at specified times, the several rate series having unconditional rate dynamics characterised by a parametric model type in several dimensions, each rate series having at least one known value comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional rate dynamics by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation and a mean of the rate change per unit interval of time, and for each pair of rate series assigning a correlation coefficient of the rate changes per unit interval of time; specifying a known or unknown rate value for each rate series and for each specified time; calculating the values of the known rate changes; calculating an unconditional multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes; and computing a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values.
  • a computer-implemented method of modelling the unknown values of several rate series at specified times the several rate series having unconditional rate dynamics being mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion or a combination of the two, in several dimensions, each rate series having at least one known value
  • the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional rate dynamics by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation, a long-term average of the rate changes per unit interval of time, a speed of mean reversion, and assigning a correlation coefficient of the rate changes for each pair of rate series; specifying, for each rate series and each specified time, a known or unknown rate value; calculating the values of the known rate changes; selecting at least one known rate for each rate series; calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes conditional on the selected at least one known rate; and calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values
  • a computer-implemented method modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the one or more issuers, the unconditional dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series being mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion, or a combination of the two, in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of: specifying unconditional dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series by assigning, for each zero coupon rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation, a long-term average of the rate changes per unit interval of time and a speed of mean reversion, and specifying for each pair of zero coupon rate series, a correlation coefficient of the rate changes; specifying trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; and calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
  • a computer-implemented method of modelling the unknown values of several rate series at specified times conditional on known values of the rate series, the rate series having unconditional rate changes that are multivariate normal and each rate series having at least one known value comprising the steps of: specifying unconditional distribution of the rate changes by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type, and assigning, for each rate change over a time interval determined by successive specified times, a standard deviation and a mean of the rate changes and assigning, for each pair of rate changes over time intervals determined by successive specified points in time, a correlation coefficient of the rate changes; specifying, for each rate series and each specified times, the known or unknown rate value; calculating the values of the known rate changes; calculating an unconditional multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes; and calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values.
  • a computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the one or more issuers, the changes in the specified zero coupon rate series having an unconditional distribution that is multivariate normal comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional distribution of the rate changes by assigning, for each specified zero coupon rate series, a parametric model type, and assigning for each rate change over a time interval determined by successive specified times, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon rate changes, and specifying, for each pair of rate changes over time intervals determined by successive specified times, a correlation coefficient of the zero coupon rate changes; specifying trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
  • a computer-implemented method of detecting the known values, of several rate series at specified times, that are extreme comprising the steps of: assigning a known or unknown rate value for each rate series and for each specified time; specifying a subset of the known rates comprising those that are to be accepted without question; specifying a confidence level and constructing, for each known rate that is not to be accepted without question and for each subset of the known rates that does not include the given known rate and that includes the known rates that are to be accepted without question, a confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, for the given rate conditional on the rates belonging to the given subset taking their known values; and iteratively constructing a subset of the known rates that are not to be accepted without question such that, for each rate belonging to the subset the value of the rate does not lie within the confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, constructed for the rate conditional on the known rates which do not belong to the subset taking their known values, and for
  • FIG. 1 is a block diagram of a modelling system according to a preferred, embodiment.
  • FIG. 2 is a process flow diagram for modelling unknown values according to a preferred embodiment.
  • the modelling system 1 is software installed on a computer 2 and comprises a modelling engine 10 which processes two sets of input data taken from two input files 20 and 21.
  • a first file contains the unconditional rate dynamics 20 for several rate series and the second file contains the incomplete rate data 21 for the several rate series.
  • the unconditional rate dynamics is stored in tabular form.
  • There is a first table where each column corresponds to a rate series and where there are three rows, the first corresponding to the parametric model type of the rate series (Brownian Motion or Geometric Brownian Motion), the second row corresponding to the standard deviation of the rate changes per unit interval of time, for the rate series, and the third row corresponding to the mean of the rate changes per unit interval of time, for the rate series.
  • Each cell of the table contains a specification of the relevant parameter.
  • each column corresponds to a rate series
  • each row corresponds to a specified point in time
  • each cell in the table contains a rate value for the rate series determined by the column of the cell at the point in time determined by the row of the cell.
  • the rows are ordered in ascending order of the associated points in timi Rate values are either known or unknown. Each unknown rate value is indicated by an asterisk "*" and each known rate value is indicated by the known numerical value.
  • the modelling engine can generate any one of four sets of outputs for storage intc output files.
  • the first set of outputs comprises the marginal distributions 30 of the unknowi rate values or of the unknown rate changes over time intervals determined by successive points in time.
  • the remaining three sets of outputs 31, 32 and 33 each comprise filled values for the unknown values so as to complete the incomplete rate data 21.
  • the second set of outputs fills the unknown values using expected rate changes 31.
  • the third set of outputs fills the unknown values using expected values 32.
  • the fourth set of outputs fills the unknown values using simulated values 33.
  • the simulated values 33 can be generated any number of times with freshly simulated values for each simulation. For each simulation, the unknown values are all simulated together.
  • the unconditional rate dynamics is specified 50 into the unconditional rate dynamics input file 20. This involves specifying, for each rate series, the parametric model, the standard deviation and the mean of the rate changes per unit interval of time, and specifying, for each pair of rate series, the correlation coefficient of the rate changes.
  • a stochastic process B (Bt)te is a one-dimensional Brownian Motion (BM) if there exist ⁇ e R and ⁇ > 0 such that : (1) B - B h is a normally distributed random variable for t x ⁇ t ,
  • time is the time underlying the assumed rate dynamics, and this may be different from calendar time. For example, time could be measured in trading days or calendar days.
  • XX - X ⁇ is a normally distributed random variable for t t ⁇ t ⁇
  • E( X W - X7 (t 2 - tl ) ⁇ j for tl ⁇ t,
  • Kj,j' pj,j' ⁇ j ⁇ j' forj,j'e ⁇ l, ... ,m ⁇ .
  • is a GBM
  • the incomplete rate data is specified 51 in the incomplete series of rates input file 20.
  • ⁇ j is the eigenvalue of co v( ⁇ , ⁇ ) corresponding to the eigenvector b j , f or j e ⁇ 1 , ... , M ⁇ . Note that ⁇ j > 0 for each j, because cov( ⁇ , ⁇ ) is non-negative definite.
  • I r is the r by r identity matrix
  • each ⁇ j is the eigenvalue of cov( ⁇ , ⁇ ) corresponding to the eigenvector bj, and [b ⁇ , ... , bjyj ⁇ is an orthonormal basis of R M .
  • Fx denote the distribution function of X and fx the density function of X, for any random variable X.
  • be a condition expressing the fact that the known rates take their known values.
  • R t J is not known and R tk 3 is known for some k ⁇ i, and R ta J is not known for k ⁇ ⁇ ⁇ i.
  • R t . ⁇ is not known and tk is known for some k > i, and R t( ⁇ is not known for i ⁇ ⁇ ⁇ k.
  • R t p is not known and R k is known for some k > i, and R ta s not known for i ⁇ ⁇ ⁇ k.
  • R j is not known and R tk is known for some k ⁇ i, and R t( ⁇ is not known for k ⁇ ⁇ i.
  • R t J is not known and R tk is known for some k > i, and R t is not known for i ⁇ ⁇ ⁇ k.
  • S is orthogonal and where ; is the eigenvalue of cov(#,#
  • Wi,...,W t are uncorrelated N(0,1) and therefore independent.
  • j - is not known and . is known for some k>i and ⁇ a is not known for i ⁇ k.
  • R (1) is a Geometric Brownian Motion and R ( ) is a Brownian Motion.
  • n the number of time intervals, to be 2.
  • condition ⁇ ⁇ x expresses the fact that the known rate changes take their known values.
  • the unknown rates are R ] (1) and R 2 2) .
  • R (1) is a GBM.
  • R j (2) is the only known rate for R (2) .
  • R (2) is a Brownian Motion. Then R ⁇ , conditional on ⁇ ,
  • R 2 2 N(0.324656,0.857143).
  • R 2 2 is normally distributed with an expected value of 0.324656 and a variance of 0.857143.
  • R (2) E(R ⁇ )
  • K be the set of known rates. For each rate x belonging to K, let us use x to denote the rate considered as a random variable and let [x] denote the known value. Let K 0 be a subset, possibly empty, of K that consists of the known rates whose values are to be accepted without question.
  • ⁇ (x,X) and ⁇ (x,X) depend on calculated conditional rate dynamics. Note also that ⁇ (x,X) is the distance, measured in standard deviations, of the known value of x from the conditional mode of x.
  • the modelling system 1 allows the modelling of the zero coupon rate curves of several bond issuers at several trading dates given a number of bond trades, where specified zero coupon rate series of the several issuers are assumed to follow a (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions.
  • a set of maturity buckets that is, a set of disjoint intervals covering all maturities of interest.
  • a representative or standard maturity falling in the maturity bucket is specified.
  • a pricing function for bonds of the issuer and a method of interpolation for zero coupon rates of the issuer are specified.
  • the rate type that is, the compounding frequency and the notional number of days in a year, of the standard maturity zero coupon rate series of the issuer is specified. These rate types may vary from one standard maturity to another for the same issuer.
  • the standard maturity zero coupon rate series, of the specified rate types, of the several issuers are assumed to follow a Brownian Motion or a Geometric Brownian Motion, or a combination of the two, in several dimensions. This involves, first, specifying, for each standard maturity zero coupon rate series of each issuer, the parametric model type (Brownian Motion or Geometric Brownian Motion), the volatility (standard deviation of the rate changes) per unit interval of time and the mean of the rate changes per unit interval of time, and, second, specifying a correlation coefficient of the rate changes for each pair of standard maturity zero coupon rate series (not necessarily of the same issuer).
  • the unit interval of time relative to which the parameters for the (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions are expressed can be measured as calendar time or as trading time.
  • the assumption of a (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions together with its associated parameters can be described as the specification of the unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics.
  • a number of trading dates, not necessarily uniformly spaced, are specified.
  • zero or more traded bonds are specified. This involves specifying, for each traded bond, the issuer of the bond, the settlement date, the maturity date, the annual coupon rate, the annual coupon frequency and the traded yield whose compounding frequency is taken to be the given annual coupon frequency.
  • a bond that traded on two dates is here treated as two traded bonds because of the two trading dates, the two settlement dates and the two traded yields. It is assumed that, for each issuer and each trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds (of the given issuer) that traded on the given trading date are distinct.
  • the specification of the trading dates and the traded bonds can be described as the specification of the traded bond data.
  • a standard maturity zero coupon rate series for a given issuer is taken to be "known” at a given trading date if there is a traded bond whose issuer is the given issuer, whose trading date is the given trading date and whose maturity, calculated from the given trading date, falls in the maturity bucket associated with the standard maturity zero coupon rate series.
  • a standard maturity zero coupon rate series for a given issuer is taken to be "unknown” at a given trading date if it is not “known” at the given trading date. It is assumed that each standard maturity zero coupon rate series is "known” at at least one trading date. Note that a standard maturity zero coupon rate series that is "known” at some trading date does not have its value, at the given trading date, known with any certainty. Both the "known" and the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates can be considered to be random.
  • the modelling method provides a way of estimating both the "known” and the "unknown” standard maturity zero coupon rates, for all issuers, all standard maturities and all trading dates, and depends on both the assumed unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and the traded bond data.
  • the modelling method employs an iterative technique for estimating the "known" and "unknown” standard maturity zero coupon rates and generates, for each issuer and each trading date, a zero coupon rate curve whose maturity points consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls.
  • the modelling of zero coupon curves involves the following steps :
  • a zero coupon rate curve is constructed whose maturity points consist of the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve.
  • Each zero coupon rate curve is constructed in such a way that pricing the traded bonds, associated with the curve, from the curve is consistent with the traded bond data associated with the curve.
  • the curves are thus calibrated against the traded bond data.
  • the curve construction employs not only the yields of the traded bonds, but also the specified pricing function for bonds of the issuer associated with the curve in question and the specified method of interpolation for zero coupon rates for the same issuer.
  • the constructed curves are calibrated against the traded bond data, but do not incorporate correlation effects (or, more precisely, covariance effects) across issuers and trading dates. The curves are used to provide initial estimates for the
  • the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are filled using the expected values of the standard maturity zero coupon rate changes conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates (for all issuers and all trading dates) taking the current estimates of their values.
  • the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates for all issuers and all trading dates, are filled with their expected values conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates (for all issuers and all trading dates) taking the current estimates of their values.
  • the filling relies on the modelling method of aspect one.
  • the filled values then provide estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. This step can be described as estimating the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates, given estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • a zero coupon rate curve is constructed for each issuer and for each trading date.
  • the maturity points of each curve consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls.
  • These curves are constructed in such a way that, first, they are calibrated against the traded bond data and, second, the constructed zero coupon rates corresponding to "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are determined by the given estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • the constructed curves provide the next estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates, using the specified methods of interpolation, if need be. This step can be described as recalibrating the estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • Steps 2 and 3 are repeated, as a pair of steps, until the successive estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates are equal (or, in practice, until the successive estimates are sufficiently close), that is, until convergence is reached. Note that the repeated execution of steps 2 and 3 allows the progressive incorporation of correlation effects across bond maturities, issuers and trading dates into the estimates of the "known" and
  • the values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates determined by the generated zero coupon rate curves are consistent with the expected values of the standard maturity zero coupon rate changes conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates taking values determined by the generated curves, or, in the alternative version, the values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates determined by the generated curves are the expected values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates conditional on the "known” standard maturity zero coupon rate taking values determined by the generated curves. This means that correlation effects across issuers, maturities and trading dates have been incorporated into the generated curves.
  • the generated curves are calibrated against the traded bond data. The two properties together justify taking the generated zero coupon rate curves to be reasonable proxies for the modes of the zero coupon rates conditional on the traded bond data or, in the alternative version, reasonable proxies for the expected values of the zero coupon curves conditional on the traded bond data.
  • the generated curves enable the pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, of bonds (of the several issuers) other than the specified traded bonds.
  • bonds of the several issuers
  • estimated portfolio values incorporate correlation effects across the trading dates, as well as across maturities and across issuers.
  • the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are filled using simulated values conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates taking values that result from convergence after the repeated execution of steps 2 and 3, where the alternative version of step 2 is not used. This manner of filling relies on the modelling method of aspect one. This step can be described as simulating the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • Step 5 Given the simulated values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates provided by step 4, a zero coupon rate curve is constructed for each issuer and for each trading date.
  • the maturity points of each curve consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls.
  • the curves are constructed in such a way that, first, they are calibrated against the traded bond data and, second, the constructed zero coupon rates corresponding to the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are determined by the simulated values provided by step 4.
  • the constructed curves are simulated and are correlated in a manner consistent with both the assumed unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and the traded bond data. Simulated values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates can be derived from the simulated curves, using the specified methods of interpolation, if need be. This step can be described as simulating the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • Steps 4 and 5 are repeated, as a pair of steps, to provide as many simulations of the calibrated zero coupon rate curves and of the associated "known" and “unknown” standard maturity zero coupon rates as is desired. These simulations are conditional on the traded bond data.
  • the simulated curves enable the pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, of bonds (of the several issuers) other than the specified traded bonds.
  • bonds of the several issuers
  • Such simulations incorporate correlation effects across the trading dates, as well as across maturities and across issuers.
  • the modelling system 1 allows the modelling of the zero coupon rate curves of several bond issuers at several trading dates given a number of bond trades, where specified zero coupon rate spread series of the several issuers are assumed to follow a (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions.
  • a set of maturity buckets is specified. It is assumed that the number of maturity buckets is the same for all issuers. For each issuer and each maturity bucket, a representative or standard maturity falling in the maturity bucket is specified.
  • the maturity buckets for each issuer are ordered in ascending order of the associated standard maturities. This ordering is used to set up a correspondence between the maturity buckets of any given issuer and those of any other issuer.
  • the standard maturities for any given issuer would normally be chosen to be equal to the corresponding standard maturities for the other issuers.
  • a pricing function for bonds of the issuer and a method of interpolation for zero coupon rates of the issuer are specified.
  • the rate type that is, the compounding frequency and the notional number of days in a year, of the standard maturity zero coupon rate series of the issuer is specified.
  • the standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series can be specified in one of two ways :
  • the standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series for the base issuer are the standard maturity zero coupon rate series for the base issuer (one for each maturity bucket of the base issuer).
  • a standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series defined to be the difference between the standard maturity zero coupon rate series associated with the given issuer and the given maturity bucket and the standard maturity zero coupon rate series associated with the base issuer and the maturity bucket, of the base issuer, that corresponds with the given maturity bucket.
  • the specified standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series can be described as series of spreads over the base issuer.
  • the standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series for the base issuer are the standard maturity zero coupon rate series for the base issuer (one for each maturity bucket of the base issuer). For each of the remaining issuers and for each maturity bucket of the given issuer, there is a standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series defined to be the difference between the standard maturity zero coupon rate series associated with the given issuer and the given maturity bucket and the standard maturity zero coupon rate series associated with the previous issuer and the maturity bucket, of the previous issuer, that corresponds with the given maturity bucket.
  • the specified standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series can be described as series of successive spreads.
  • Brownian Motion in several dimensions. This involves, first, specifying, for each spread series of each issuer, the parametric model type (Geometric Brownian Motion or Brownian Motion), the volatility (standard deviation of the spread changes) per unit interval of time and the mean of the spread changes per unit interval of time, and, second, specifying a correlation coefficient of the spread changes for each pair of spread series.
  • the unit interval of time relative to which the parameters for the (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions are expressed can be measured as calendar time or as trading time.
  • the assumption of a (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions together with its associated parameters can be described as the specification of the unconditional spread dynamics.
  • a number of trading dates, not necessarily uniformly spaced, are specified.
  • zero or more traded bonds are specified. This involves specifying, for each traded bond, the issuer of the bond, the settlement date, the maturity date, the annual coupon rate, the annual coupon frequency and the traded yield whose compounding frequency is taken to be the given annual coupon frequency.
  • a bond that traded on two dates is here treated as two traded bonds because of the two trading dates, the two settlement dates and the two traded yields. It is assumed that, for each issuer and each trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds, of the given issuer, that traded on the given trading date are distinct.
  • the specification of the trading dates and the traded bonds can be described as the specification of the traded bond data.
  • a standard maturity zero coupon rate series for a given issuer is taken to be "known” at a given trading date if there is a traded bond whose issuer is the given issuer, whose trading date is the given trading date and whose maturity, calculated from the given trading date, falls in the maturity bucket associated with the standard maturity zero coupon rate series.
  • a standard maturity zero coupon rate series for a given issuer is taken to be "unknown” at a given trading date if it is not “known” at the given trading date.
  • a spread series that is "known” at some trading date does not have its value, at the given trading date, known with any certainty. Both the "known" and the “unknown” spreads, as well as the "known” and the “unknown” standard maturity zero coupon rate series, can be considered to be random.
  • the modelling method provides a way of estimating both the "known” and the "unknown” standard maturity zero coupon rates (for all issuers, all standard maturities and all trading dates) and depends on both the assumed unconditional spread dynamics and the traded bond data.
  • the modelling method employs an iterative technique for estimating the "known" and "unknown” standard maturity zero coupon rates and generates, for each issuer and each trading date, a zero coupon rate curve whose maturity points consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls.
  • the modelling method involves the following steps :
  • a zero coupon rate curve is constructed whose maturity points consist of the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve.
  • Each zero coupon rate curve is constructed in such a way that pricing the traded bonds, associated with the curve, from the curve is consistent with the traded bond data associated with the curve. The curves are thus calibrated against the traded bond data.
  • the curve construction employs not only the yields of the traded bonds, but also the specified pricing function for bonds of the issuer associated with the curve in question and the specified method of interpolation for zero coupon rates for the same issuer.
  • the constructed curves are calibrated against the traded bond data, but do not incorporate correlation effects across issuers and across trading dates.
  • the curves are used to provide initial estimates for the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates, and no interpolation is necessary to calculate these estimates from the curves. This step can be described as calculating initial estimates for the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • a zero coupon rate curve is constructed for each issuer and trading date.
  • the maturity points of each curve consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls.
  • These curves are constructed in such a way that, first, they are calibrated against the traded bond data and, second, the constructed zero coupon rates corresponding to "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are determined by the given estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • the constructed curves provide the next estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates, using the specified methods of interpolation, if need be. This step can be described as recalibrating the estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Steps 2 and 3 are repeated, as a pair of steps, until the successive estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates are equal, that is, until convergence is reached. Note that the repeated execution of steps 2 and 3 allows the progressive incorporation of correlation effects across bond maturities, issuers and trading dates into the estimates of the "known" and "unknown” standard maturity zero coupon rates. When convergence is reached, the most recent iterates of the curves constructed in step 3 can be taken to be reasonable proxies for the modes of the zero coupon rates conditional on the traded bond data.
  • the generated zero coupon rate curves have two notable properties. First, the values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates determined by the generated zero coupon rate curves are consistent with the expected values of the spread changes conditional on the "known" spreads taking values determined by the generated zero coupon rate curves, where the calculation of the expected values is understood to rely on the affine approximations that result from step 2. This means that correlation effects across issuers, maturities and trading dates have been incorporated into the generated curves. Second, the generated curves are calibrated against the traded bond data. The two properties together justify taking the generated zero coupon rate curves to be reasonable proxies for the modes of the zero coupon curves rates conditional on the traded bond data.
  • the generated curves enable the pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, of bonds (of the several issuers) other than the specified traded bonds.
  • bonds of the several issuers
  • Such estimated portfolio values incorporate correlation effects across the trading dates, as well as across maturities and issuers. Note that it is possible to include specified trading dates on which no specified traded bonds of any issuer traded. An example might be a future trading date.
  • a further two steps allow the approximate simulation of the zero coupon rate curves and of the "known" and "unknown” standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • the idea behind these two steps is that the values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates are largely determined by the traded bond data and the conditional variation is largely concentrated in the "unknown” spreads. Note that the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates and the “unknown” spreads together determine the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
  • the "unknown" spreads are filled using simulated values conditional both on the "known” spreads taking the values that result from convergence after the repeated execution of steps 2 and 3 and on the linearised constraint equations, that also result from convergence, being satisfied. Note that, because of the affine approximations employed, the filled “unknown” spread values are not, in general, quite consistent with the values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates that result from convergence.
  • a zero coupon rate curve is constructed for each issuer and each trading date.
  • the maturity points of each curve consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls.
  • the curves are constructed in such a way that, first, they are calibrated against the traded bond data and, second, the constructed zero coupon rates corresponding to the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are determined by the simulated values provided by step 4.
  • the constructed curves are simulated and are correlated in a manner consistent with both the assumed unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and the traded bond data. Simulated values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates can be derived from the simulated curves, using the specified methods of interpolation, if need be. This step can be described as simulating the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Steps 4 and 5 are repeated, as a pair of steps, to provide as many simulations of the calibrated zero coupon rate curves and of the associated "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates as is desired. These simulations are conditional on the traded bond data.
  • the simulated curves enable the pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, of bonds (of the several issuers) other than the specified traded bonds.
  • bonds of the several issuers
  • Such simulations incorporate correlation effects across the trading dates, as well as across maturities and issuers.
  • P(y) be the total price of a given bond as a function of the bond's yield-to-maturity, quoted on some trading date. Note that it is possible to use different bond pricing functions for different bond issuers or even for different bonds of a given issuer. By way of example, let us give the following generalisation of the Reserve Bank of Australia's pricing formula for government bonds :
  • F is the annual coupon frequency (a divisor of 12)
  • m is the number of days from settlement to the next coupon date (after settlement)
  • M is the number of days from the last coupon date on or before settlement to the next coupon date (after settlement),
  • Coupon is the coupon rate of the bond, expressed as a decimal, and EXDAYS is the length of the ex coupon period in days.
  • This formula uses bill pricing if settlement falls in the last coupon period. If settlement does not fall in the last coupon period, we have n
  • X represent an interpolation function : for a given maturity ⁇ in days and a given 2;ero coupon rate curve C, Z( ⁇ , C) will represent the interpolated continuously compounding zero coupon rate of maturity r. Note that it is possible to use different interpolation functions for different issuers.
  • B is the notional number of days in a year
  • C ((SJ, r j )) j - ⁇ ,..., n be a curve for some trading date and let y be the known yield of a bond whose maturity is r days from the given trading date.
  • r > s n if n > 1 and r > 0 if n — 0.
  • C[( ⁇ , x)] be C U ⁇ (T, X) ⁇ .
  • N + 1 trading dates DQ, . . . , DN of interest where N > 0 and DQ ⁇ . . . ⁇ DN.
  • N + 1 associated times to ⁇ ⁇ ⁇ , t/v The unit of time for the times to, ⁇ ⁇ . , tj could be one trading day or one calendar day.
  • K ⁇ k, i, m l ⁇ k ⁇ K ⁇ 0 ⁇ i ⁇ N ⁇ l ⁇ m ⁇ ⁇ ⁇ k) A (3 ⁇ )(l ⁇ ⁇ ⁇ N(k, i) ⁇ ⁇ ' f > G B )
  • K(k, i, m) depends both on ⁇ and on the maturity buckets
  • ⁇ ( ⁇ > ft,i ⁇ ,i2,m) ⁇ ,,- W ⁇ /p ⁇ t)/ ⁇ ln(R ⁇ ( )/ ⁇ (m)) if R ⁇ (m) is a GBM
  • y y)) ⁇ (fc , 4 , m) .
  • X ( (fc,i, m ))-.ir(fc,i, m ) by filling with simulated values.
  • We can then recalibrate the "known" rates by putting ⁇ C(X, ⁇ t), and take R(X, ⁇ ) to be an approximate random drawing of (R ⁇ (TM ) (k ,i, m ) conditional on the traded bond data it.
  • K is a / ⁇ -dimensional Brownian Motion.
  • ⁇ (k> (r ⁇ ) be the mean of (the changes in) ⁇ (k m) per unit interval of time, for each (ft, m), and let cov(( m ), ( .)) be the (m) and X (k ) (m') per unit interval
  • K(k,i,m) l ⁇ k ⁇ K A 0 ⁇ i ⁇ N A 1 ⁇ m ⁇ ⁇ (k)
  • R(X,Y) (S (k ,i,m)(X ⁇ Y) + S ⁇ 1> i, m ⁇ l (X,Y) ⁇ ⁇ k> 1 ⁇ ) (k,i,m)
  • each ' m follows from the assumption that each S ⁇ (m) is "known” at some date.
  • L ⁇ ' 1 '" ⁇ is the time index of the "known" spread of the form S ⁇ (m) that is closest in time to Slf k ⁇ a)) (m).
  • ⁇ ( ⁇ ' m) There may be two choices for ⁇ ( ⁇ ' m) .
  • AK* ⁇ k,i,m K*(k,i,m) A K*(k,i-l,m).
  • K ⁇ k,i,m l ⁇ k ⁇ K A 0 ⁇ i ⁇ N A l ⁇ m ⁇ ⁇ (k) A (3 ⁇ )(l ⁇ a ⁇ N(k,i) A T ⁇ G B%>).
  • V*(k,i ⁇ ,i 2 ,m)
  • each standard maturity implied volatility is then defined to be "known” at a given date if an option traded on the given date and the maturity of the option fell in the bucket associated with the standard maturity and the underlying asset of the option is that associated with the implied volatility.
  • each standard maturity implied volatility is "known” at at least one date.
  • the algorithms described for modelling zero coupon rate curves carry over to the modelling of implied volatility curves except that there is no calibration step because the observed implied volatilities are given directly.
  • the methodology can handle real, as opposed to nominal, zero coupon rates or spreads and capital-indexed bonds.
  • One can also combine the modelling of real and nominal zero coupon rates or spreads.
  • X 0 X( 0 ).
  • Y n C(X n - 1 , ⁇ ) and X n £ X(Y n ).
  • 0.
  • n ⁇ K (the number of maturity buckets for issuer k), and, for j e ⁇ l,...,n ⁇ ,
  • R w is the pricing function specified for bonds of issuer k. Note that the left hand side of the equation is a differentiable function of the zero coupon rate vector
  • R f w (m) is known because R k) (m) is "unknown" (- ⁇ K(k, ⁇ ,m)).
  • each standard maturity zero coupon rate spread (successive spread or spread over the base issuer) is “known” (that is, each zero coupon rate figuring in the spread (each leg, say) is “known") at at least one of the specified times t 0 , t x , ... , t N (or, equivalently, at at least one of the specified trading dates), but also that each of these spread series has, at at least one of the specified times, each leg “unknown”.
  • this is a stronger requirement than that each spread series be "unknown” at at least one of the specified times : we require that, at some time, each leg of the spread be “unknown”. This new requirement can always be satisfied by adding, if need be, a new date (and associated time), at which all the zero coupon rates are necessarily “unknown", to the set of specified trading dates.
  • the "known" zero coupon rates have unknown values (are unknown) and the "unknown” zero coupon rates have known values (are known).
  • each spread series has, at some trading date, each leg "unknown” (this is not equivalent to each spread series being "unknown” at some trading date). Thus each spread is known at some trading date.
  • each calibration equation as a function of the unknown spread changes figuring in the equation, is replaced by its affine approximation, and we add (to the conditioning) a linearised constraint for each calibration equation.
  • linearised constraints need to be recomputed at each step in the iteration.
  • the "known" and “unknown” zero coupon rates together determine the calibrated standard maturity curves based on expected zero coupon rate changes.
  • a one-dimensional mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion is a stochastic process of the form exp(X) where X - (X t ) R is a mean-reverting Brownian Motion.
  • X t+&t is also normally distributed, conditional on the known value for X t .
  • X t+&t is also normally distributed, conditional on the known value for X t .
  • This analysis is easily adapted to mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motions and can be carried through to the application to modelling zero coupon rate curves. It is straight-forward to combine mean-reverting Brownian Motions and mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motions.
  • Brownian Motion assumption implies that rate changes in several dimensions are serially uncorrelated and, in fact, are serially independent.
  • rate series a number of specified points in time and a set of incomplete rate data and that each rate series has a known value at at least one of the specified points in time.
  • parametric model type we have, for each rate series, a specification of its parametric model type as normal or lognormal.
  • the present invention provides commercial value in the field of financial modelling. It may be used to provide more accurate input rate data for the historical or Monte Carlo simulation of portfolio values and for the more accurate pricing (and hedging) of individual financial instruments or of portfolios of financial instruments. These applications are important to investment banks and other financial institutions for assessing the values of deals and trading portfolios and for measuring the risks arising out of deals and trading portfolios. More accurate methods of assessing value have direct effects on the profitability of trading activities. More accurate methods of measuring risk permit more effective management of risk and more efficient allocation of risk capital.
  • the present invention allows missing rates in historical rate series to be filled in a manner that is statistically consistent with observed rates.
  • rate changes derived from filled historical rate series are used to simulate future values of trading portfolios which, in turn, are used to derive measures of the credit and market risk of the trading portfolios. More accurate methods of filling historical rate data lead to more accurate measures of risk.
  • Monte Carlo simulations of the credit or market risk of trading portfolios are normally based on complete sets of current rates.
  • the present invention allows Monte Carlo simulations to be based on incomplete sets of recent rates.
  • a further advantage of the present invention is that it allows the modelling of value and risk to be based on specific hypotheses or scenarios concerning the future levels of rates. This allows greater refinement in the so-called "stress testing" of portfolios where the impact of specific adverse rate scenarios on portfolio values is analysed.
  • the present invention may also be used for the more accurate pricing (and hedging) of financial instruments.
  • Unobserved input rates required for pricing models may be estimated or simulated in a manner that takes account of other rates, possibly observed at other times.
  • the option's implied volatility may be estimated or simulated from the calculated implied volatilities of recently traded options (on the same asset) of possibly different maturities. Note that the implied volatility of a traded option is the volatility, over the life of the option, of the price of the underlying asset of the option which, when used as the input in an option pricing model, gives a fair value equal to observed market price of the option.
  • Another possibility for valuing options and other types of derivative financial instruments is to use the conditional rate dynamics based on an incomplete set of recent rates to simulate contingent pay-offs. Simulated payoffs would allow the estimation of the expected value of a pay-off and this could be discounted to the present using the appropriate risk-free rate to provide a fair value. This approach would require a shift from the real world dynamics to risk-neutral dynamics.
  • the present invention also has potential application to time series other than the rate series of financial markets.
  • the present invention can be expressed as a computer program or software to cause a computer to perform the method.
  • the computer program can have data input means to receive the assumed unconditional dynamics or unconditional distribution, as appropriate, and the incomplete rate data or traded bond data, as appropriate.
  • the computer program can have data output means to output the modelled values.
  • the computer program can have a modelling engine to carry out the steps defined by the method.
  • conditional zero coupon rate dynamics to denote the zero coupon rate dynamics implied by the unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and the traded bond data [specified bond trades.
  • the base issuer may be chosen to be the Commonwealth of Australia.
  • the maturities of the specified zero coupon rate series for the two issuers can correspond.
  • a constructed zero coupon rate curve may include maturity points corresponding to the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are associated with the curve.
  • conditional zero coupon rate dynamics can be used to denote the zero coupon rate dynamics implied by the unconditional zero coupon rate spread dynamics and the traded bond data specified bond trades.
  • the step of populating the unknown rates with simulated values may be carried out by taking a random drawing from the multidimensional conditional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes and then inferring the simulated values from the random drawing of the unknown rate changes and the known rate values.
  • rate dynamics is understood to mean a probabilistic model of how rate series change in value over time.
  • conditional rate dynamics denotes the rate dynamics implied by the unconditional rate dynamics and the known rate values.

Abstract

A computer-implemented method of modelling unknown values of several rate series at predetermined times, the several rate series having unconditional rate dynamics characterised by a parametric model type in a plurality of dimensions, each rate series having at least one known value.

Description

CONDITIONAL RATE MODELLING Field of Invention
The invention relates to conditional rate modelling and, in particular, to modelling unknown values of several rate series at specified times.
This invention has been developed primarily for use in modelling the zero coupon rate curves of several bond issuers given limited trading data and will be described hereinafter with reference to this application. However, it will be appreciated that the invention is not limited to that particular field of use.
Background of the Invention
Institutions that are active in financial markets routinely apply mathematical models to value financial instruments in their trading portfolios. A valuation model typically takes as input the current values of a number of market rates and gives as output a theoretical price, or fair value, of the instrument in question. This allows the valuation of a financial instrument that may not have traded recently, provided that the input market rates are available.
These input market rates are typically the traded prices of simpler financial instruments of which an example is a foreign exchange rate. Market rates are only known if a trade took place in the relevant instrument during the time interval of interest. If a trade did not take place, one could use the rate corresponding to the last trade that took place, but that will cause inaccuracy because of the lack of currency of the rate.
A basic use of valuation models is to determine the daily profit and loss of trading portfolios. This involves comparing the value of a trading portfolio at the end of one trading day with its value at the end of the previous trading day, and requires the valuation of financial instruments that may not have traded in the course of the trading day. Valuation models are also used to inform trading decisions and to assess the risks arising out of trading portfolios. Market risk is the risk of the value of a trading portfolio decreasing. Credit risk is the risk of the counter-parties of trades defaulting on their contractual obligations. The amount of loss attributable to a default depends, at least in part, on the market value of the trades of the defaulting counter-party at the time of default.
The analysis of market risk involves making probabilistic assumptions about how market rates may change in the future. The impact of possible market rate changes on the value of a trading portfolio is then quantified and various measures of risk can be calculated.
A common method of market risk assessment is historical simulation. Historically observed rate changes of several rate series together are assumed to be statistically independent and to form a representative random sample and are applied to current rates. The resulting sets of rates (one for each historical time interval) are then used to revalue an existing trading portfolio. This gives a set of hypothetical future portfolio values used to calculate measures of market risk arising out of the trading portfolio. However, this method disadvantageously requires gaps in the historical rate series to have been filled before the analysis begins. It also assumes that a complete set of current rates exists.
One known approach is to set each unknown rate to its previous known value. This can cause long sequences of repeated values, which leads to underestimation of risk, and sudden large jumps to the next known value, which leads to overestimation of risk.
Another approach is to fill gaps in each rate series by linearly interpolating between the known rates. This involves graphing, for each rate series, the known values, drawing straight lines between successive known values and reading off the unknown rates from the resulting graph. This approach tends to cause underestimation of risk because it ignores the inherent variation in rates and does not take into account the fact that the rate series are correlated A significant disadvantage of prior art methods of modelling unknown rates is that they do not take account of all the known rates, including those of other rate series and those known at other times, that are related to the unknown rates. The effect of this is inaccuracy in any pricing or analysis of risk that depends on such rates.
Object of the Invention
It is an object of the present invention to provide a modelling unknown values of several rate series at specified times that overcomes or substantially ameliorates one or more of the disadvantages of the prior art, or to provide a useful alternative.
Summary of the Invention
According to a first aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of modelling unknown values of several rate series at specified times, the several rate series having unconditional rate dynamics characterised by a parametric model type in several dimensions, each rate series having at least one known value, the method, comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional rate dynamics by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation and a mean of the rate change per unit interval of time, and for each pair of rate series assigning a correlation coefficient of the rate changes per unit interval of time; specifying a known or unknown rate value for each rate series and for each specified time; calculating the values of the known rate changes; calculating an unconditional multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes; and computing a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values.
According to a second aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the issuers, the specified zero coupon rate series having unconditional dynamics characterised by a parametric model type in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of : specifying the unconditional dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series by assigning for each zero coupon rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon rate changes per unit interval of time, and assigning a correlation coefficient of the rate zero coupon changes per unit interval of time for each pair of zero coupon rate series; specifying the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series at the specified trading dates conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
According to a third aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the issuers, the number of specified zero coupon rate series of each issuer being equal and the zero coupon rate series determining zero coupon rate spread series having unconditional dynamics characterised by a parametric model type in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of : specifying the unconditional dynamics of the zero coupon rate spread series by assigning, for each zero coupon rate spread series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon rate spread changes per unit interval of time, and assigning a correlation coefficient of the zero coupon rate spread changes per unit interval of time for each pair of zero coupon rate spread series; specifying the trades of the one or more issuers; and calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the specified trades in the one or more issuers.
According to a fourth aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of modelling the unknown values of several rate series at specified times, the several rate series having unconditional rate dynamics being mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion or a combination of the two, in several dimensions, each rate series having at least one known value, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional rate dynamics by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation, a long-term average of the rate changes per unit interval of time, a speed of mean reversion, and assigning a correlation coefficient of the rate changes for each pair of rate series; specifying, for each rate series and each specified time, a known or unknown rate value; calculating the values of the known rate changes; selecting at least one known rate for each rate series; calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes conditional on the selected at least one known rate; and calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values using the multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes conditional on the selected at least one known rate.
According to a fifth of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the one or more issuers, the unconditional dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series being mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion, or a combination of the two, in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of: specifying unconditional dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series by assigning, for each zero coupon rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation, a long-term average of the rate changes per unit interval of time and a speed of mean reversion, and specifying for each pair of zero coupon rate series, a correlation coefficient of the rate changes; specifying trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; and calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers. According to a sixth aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the issuers, the number of specified zero coupon rate series of each issuer being equal and the specified zero coupon rate series of the bond issuers determining zero coupon rate spread series, having unconditional dynamics characterised by mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion, or a combination of the two, in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional dynamics of the zero coupon rate spread series by assigning, for each zero coupon rate spread series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation, a long-term average of the rate spread changes per unit interval of time and a speed of mean reversion, and assigning for each pair of zero coupon rate spread series, the correlation coefficient of the zero coupon rate spread changes: specifying trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; calculating the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers iteratively.
According to a seventh aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of modelling the unknown values of several rate series at specified times conditional on known values of the rate series, the rate series having unconditional rate changes that are multivariate normal and each rate series having at least one known value, the method comprising the steps of: specifying unconditional distribution of the rate changes by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type, and assigning, for each rate change over a time interval determined by successive specified times, a standard deviation and a mean of the rate changes and assigning, for each pair of rate changes over time intervals determined by successive specified points in time, a correlation coefficient of the rate changes; specifying, for each rate series and each specified times, the known or unknown rate value; calculating the values of the known rate changes; calculating an unconditional multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes; and calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values.
According to an eighth aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the one or more issuers, the changes in the specified zero coupon rate series having an unconditional distribution that is multivariate normal, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional distribution of the rate changes by assigning, for each specified zero coupon rate series, a parametric model type, and assigning for each rate change over a time interval determined by successive specified times, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon rate changes, and specifying, for each pair of rate changes over time intervals determined by successive specified times, a correlation coefficient of the zero coupon rate changes; specifying trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
According to a ninth aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the issuers, the number of specified zero coupon rate series of each issuer being equal and the zero coupon rate series of the bond issuers determining zero coupon rate spread series wherein changes over time in the spread series have an unconditional distribution being multivariate normal, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional distribution of the zero coupon spread rate changes by assigning, for each zero coupon spread rate series, a parametric model type, by specifying, for each zero coupon spread rate change over a time interval determined by successive specified times, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon spread rate changes, and by specifying, for each pair of zero coupon rate spread changes over time intervals determined by successive specified times, a correlation coefficient of the zero coupon spread rate changes; specifying the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; and calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series at the specified trading dates conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers iteratively.
According to a tenth aspect of the invention there is provided a computer-implemented method of detecting the known values, of several rate series at specified times, that are extreme, the method comprising the steps of: assigning a known or unknown rate value for each rate series and for each specified time; specifying a subset of the known rates comprising those that are to be accepted without question; specifying a confidence level and constructing, for each known rate that is not to be accepted without question and for each subset of the known rates that does not include the given known rate and that includes the known rates that are to be accepted without question, a confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, for the given rate conditional on the rates belonging to the given subset taking their known values; and iteratively constructing a subset of the known rates that are not to be accepted without question such that, for each rate belonging to the subset the value of the rate does not lie within the confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, constructed for the rate conditional on the known rates which do not belong to the subset taking their known values, and for each known rate which does not belong to the subset and which is not to be accepted without question, the value of the rate lies within the confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, constructed for the rate conditional on the known rates, with the exception of the given known rate, which do not belong to the subset taking their known values.
According to another aspect of the invention there is provided a A method of constructing, for each known rate that is not to be accepted without question and for each subset of the known rates that includes the known rates that are to be accepted without question and does not include the given rate, a confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, for the given rate conditional on the rates belonging to the given subset taking their known values, the construction of the confidence interval relying on the marginal probability distribution of the rate according to any one of the first, third or eighth aspects of the invention.
It can be seen that there is provided a method of modelling unknown values of several rate series at specified times which provides more accurate results that can be obtained by using prior art methods.
Brief Description of the Drawing Preferred embodiments of the invention will now be described, by way of example only, with reference to the accompanying drawings in which:
FIG. 1 is a block diagram of a modelling system according to a preferred, embodiment; and
FIG. 2 is a process flow diagram for modelling unknown values according to a preferred embodiment.
Detailed Description of the Drawings
Referring to Figure 1, the modelling system 1 is software installed on a computer 2 and comprises a modelling engine 10 which processes two sets of input data taken from two input files 20 and 21. A first file contains the unconditional rate dynamics 20 for several rate series and the second file contains the incomplete rate data 21 for the several rate series. The unconditional rate dynamics is stored in tabular form. There is a first table where each column corresponds to a rate series and where there are three rows, the first corresponding to the parametric model type of the rate series (Brownian Motion or Geometric Brownian Motion), the second row corresponding to the standard deviation of the rate changes per unit interval of time, for the rate series, and the third row corresponding to the mean of the rate changes per unit interval of time, for the rate series. Each cell of the table contains a specification of the relevant parameter. There is a second table where both the rows and the columns correspond to rate series and each cell in the table contains the value of the correlation coefficient of the rate changes for the pair of rate series determined by the row and the column of the cell. The incomplete rate data is also stored in tabular form. There is a table where each column corresponds to a rate series, each row corresponds to a specified point in time and each cell in the table contains a rate value for the rate series determined by the column of the cell at the point in time determined by the row of the cell. The rows are ordered in ascending order of the associated points in timi Rate values are either known or unknown. Each unknown rate value is indicated by an asterisk "*" and each known rate value is indicated by the known numerical value. On selection, the modelling engine can generate any one of four sets of outputs for storage intc output files. The first set of outputs comprises the marginal distributions 30 of the unknowi rate values or of the unknown rate changes over time intervals determined by successive points in time. The remaining three sets of outputs 31, 32 and 33 each comprise filled values for the unknown values so as to complete the incomplete rate data 21. The second set of outputs fills the unknown values using expected rate changes 31. The third set of outputs fills the unknown values using expected values 32. The fourth set of outputs fills the unknown values using simulated values 33. The simulated values 33 can be generated any number of times with freshly simulated values for each simulation. For each simulation, the unknown values are all simulated together.
Referring to Figure 2, the unconditional rate dynamics is specified 50 into the unconditional rate dynamics input file 20. This involves specifying, for each rate series, the parametric model, the standard deviation and the mean of the rate changes per unit interval of time, and specifying, for each pair of rate series, the correlation coefficient of the rate changes.
Conditional Rate Modellin : (Geometric) Brownian Motion
A stochastic process B = (Bt)te is a one-dimensional Brownian Motion (BM) if there exist μ e R and σ > 0 such that : (1) B - Bh is a normally distributed random variable for tx< t ,
(2) E(Bh - BH ) = (t2 - tl) μ for ^ ≤ t,, (3) v|( B -Bh ) = (t2 - ti σ2 for tx < t2, and (4) Bh -Bh and B . -B < are independent whenever rnfttj.ynf . ]) = 0> for tx ≤ tj and tj'≤ t2', where m is Lebesgue measure on R. Note that (1) - (3) imply that Bt+ι - Bt ~ N(μ, σ2) for any t e R. A stochastic process B = (Br)teR is a one-dimensional Geometric Brownian Motion (GBM) if (ln(Bt))te R is a one-dimensional Brownian Motion.
We start with m rate series R(1), ... , R(m) where m > 1.
5 Each R(,) = (Rf 0) ) R is a stochastic process, where Rt ) is the value of the jth rate series at time t. We assume that time here is the time underlying the assumed rate dynamics, and this may be different from calendar time. For example, time could be measured in trading days or calendar days. Now each R0) is going to be either a BM or a GBM. i nr R*ω if Ri3HstobeaBM ' M , „
10 Put X.ω = ' J ^ for je {1, ... ,m} and teR. ln(R,ω) if Rω istobeaGBM,
Figure imgf000012_0001
df
Then X =(Xt ) R is a vector-valued stochastic process.
We also have the stochastic process X<J)
Figure imgf000012_0002
for each je {1, ... ,m} .
Now each X ω is going to be a BM. But we make the stronger assumption that X is 15 an m-dimensional Brownian Motion; that is, we assume that there exists μ = (μj) e R" and a matrix = (KJ, >)Q, J'), where 1 < j, j' < m, such that :
(1) Xt — Xt is a normally distributed random variable for tt< t^,
(2) E( Xh - Xh ) = (t2- tj) μ for t,≤ j,
(3) cov( X - Xh , Xh - Xh ) = (t2- 1 ) K for t,≤ t,, 0 and (4) X,2 - X and Xh, - Xt , are independent whenever m([t1, t2]n[t1',t2']) = 0, for tj≤ ^ and ≤ -
Note that (1) - (4) imply that each Xω is a one-dimensional BM. df , hi particular, if we put σj =^fC}tJ for je {1, ... , m}, we have :
(1) XX - X^ is a normally distributed random variable for tt≤ t^ , (2) E( X W - X7 = (t2 - tl) μj for tl< t,,
(3) cov(χW-X«, W- W)σj2 for t^, and (4) X ' - X ' and xj) - X,Φ are independent whenever
Figure imgf000013_0001
for tx< ,and ≤ -
μ = is the mean vector of rate changes per unit interval of time and
Figure imgf000013_0002
κ = κj ' j ' )(j ' j ' ) is the covariance matrix of rate changes per unit interval of time
Figure imgf000013_0003
df unit interval of time and a correlation matrix P = (Pj»j')(j>j') > wnere σι-~ Kj,j anα-
_. J,J
P Then Kj,j' = pj,j' σj σj' forj,j'e{l, ... ,m}.
Figure imgf000013_0004
Note that if either of σj or σj' is zero, then pj,j' is undefined, but Kj,j> = Q, SO that any value for Pj>j' (say, 0 or 1) will yield the correct value for κj>j' .
Note that the term volatility is used to denote the standard deviation of rate changes.
Note also that if R® is a GBM, we have X ^ - x[j) = ln(R^ )- ln(RJ;-) ) = ln^ /R{J)). For R(i) a GBM, we assume that RJ}) > 0 for all teR, because ln(x) is not defined for x < 0. df
For j e {1, ... ,m}, let us define A^2 = X£° - XjΛ for tj≤ t2.
We then define for tx≤ t2.
Figure imgf000013_0005
The assumption of an m-dimensional Brownian Motion then reduces to : (1) Aht ~ N(( t2- tj) μ, ( t7) ) for tx< t2, and (2) t and Δ^, are independent whenever m([t1,t2]n[t1',t2']) = 0, for ti ≤ ^ and ≤ - This constitutes our assumed unconditional rate dynamics.
Referring to Figure 2, the incomplete rate data is specified 51 in the incomplete series of rates input file 20.
We now restrict our attention to n+1 times t0, tj, ... , tn satisfying t0 < t2 < ... < tn, where n > 1. We then have the n time intervals [t0, tx], ... , [t^ , tn] . We suppose that the values of some of the rates
Figure imgf000014_0001
where j e {1, ... , m} and i e {0,1, ... , n}, are known and the others are unknown . We wish to determine what the known rates imply about the unknown rates, given the assumed unconditional rate dynamics. In particular, we wish to: (1) determine the probability distribution of the unknown rates,
(2) estimate the unknown rates, and (3) simulate the unknown rates.
First observe that Δ^ is known if and only if R^and R are both known, for i < i'.
Let us define
Figure imgf000014_0002
r J e {1, .. • , m} and i e { 1, ... , n}, df and Δt(. =t. -tM for i e { 1, ... , n}.
Then the Brownian Motion assumption implies that E Δ(/) ) = Δt( .
and COVI VΔV . ) , Δ , ) I)= Si ι,ι ., At i K j..j ,, , where δ ,,,, ,, =\Q j . . . ., , is the ronecker delta
function. The Brownian Motion assumption also implies that
Δ >)1≤j.≤mιl≤,,„ is multivariate normal in R"1".
Referring to Figure 2, the runs and the unknown rate changes are determined 52. Let us call a known rate chang σe of the form Δφ tt,t,r a run if :
(l) l <j < m,
(2) 0 < i < i'≤ n, and (3) RJ is unknown for all k satisfying i < k < i' , and let the length of the run be i'-i.
Every run is of length > 1.
If , is a run of length 1, we have Δ 'I = Δφ and RΦ and RΦ are both known, and, for any run Apt t , both R; ' and R}p ave known.
Suppose that there are M runs. Let ξ be a random vector in RM whose components consist of the runs. Then there is a vector x e RM such that the condition ξ = x expresses the fact that the known rate changes take their known values. Now suppose that there are N unknowns of the form Δφ where 1 < j < m and 1 < i < n. Let θ be a random vector in RN whose components consist of these unknown rate changes.
I
For any run Δ^., , we have Δ^,., = ∑Δφ , so that all the components of ξ and θ are k=i+l
of the form /t .
Figure imgf000015_0001
and δk, tkκ r
Figure imgf000015_0002
ffξ\ fξS\
Thus we can calculate E and
Figure imgf000015_0003
We also have multivariate normal in R M+N
Consider a run ξα of length > 2, for some α e {1, ... , M}. Then ξa = ∑Δφ for some j and i' > i+1, where Δ^ , ... , Aψ are all unknown. k=i+l
So there exist o* e { 1, ... , N}, for k = i+1, ... , i', satisfying ξa = ∑^ • k=i+l
This algebraic dependence is preserved almost everywhere (a.e. or with probability
one) if we replace ξ by any random ξ' such that
Figure imgf000016_0001
This follows from the proof of the following result
Figure imgf000016_0002
Let and be random vectors. Suppose that each ξt is an affine
Figure imgf000016_0004
Figure imgf000016_0003
function of θx , ... , ΘN . Then, for any ξ' such that E(ξ') = E(ξ) and
Figure imgf000016_0005
Figure imgf000016_0006
Proof
η') = cov(η, η).
Figure imgf000016_0007
Let i e { 1, ... , M}. It is enough to show that ξ] - ξ. a.e„ We have σ > = σε because cov(η, η) = cov(η', η')-
First suppose that σ .. = 0. Then
Figure imgf000016_0008
= E[ξ ) a.e. and ξ. - E{ξl) a.e..
But E{ξ,) = E(ξ , because E(η) = E(η'). Thus = ξ\ a.e..
Now suppose that σ£] > 0.
But h i — A{ + 2_!
Figure imgf000016_0009
for some real numbers λt , }. , ... , λN
Figure imgf000016_0010
= λi j cov\ξij) (because cov(η, η) = cov(η', η'))
;=l
so that
Figure imgf000017_0001
p tø wfe{1 °'.ι»» a.e. σ ; σ#,
ButE(< )= E(< ) and σ . = σ?. . Thus we have ξ7ξt a.e..
Referring to Figure 2, cov(ξ,ξ) is decomposed 53.
We now wish to determine the distribution of θ conditional on ξ = x.
Now cov(ξ,ξ) is an M by M symmetric real matrix. So there is an orthonormal basis
{bi, ... , bM} of R consisting of eigenvectors of cov(ξ,ξ). Put B
Figure imgf000017_0002
) . Then B
is orthogonal and where λj is the eigenvalue of
Figure imgf000017_0003
co v(ξ,ξ) corresponding to the eigenvector b j , f or j e { 1 , ... , M } . Note that λj > 0 for each j, because cov(ξ, ξ) is non-negative definite.
Without loss of generality, there is a unique re {0, 1, ... , M} such that
X\ ≥ ... ≥ λj- > λr_| = ... = λ [ = 0 (reordering the columns of B and renaming the eigenvalues, if necessary). Put D , an M by M matrix.
Figure imgf000018_0001
df
We also put Z - O L(ξ-E(ξ)).
Figure imgf000018_0002
so that Zj = 0 for j = r+1, ... , M.
We also have cov(Z,Z) = Ε(ZZτ) (E(Z) = 0)
= E(DBτ(ξ-E(ξ))(ξ-E(ξ))τBD) = DBτE((ξ-E(ξ))(ξ-E(ξ))τ)BD = DBτcov(ξ,ξ)BD
Figure imgf000018_0003
where Ir is the r by r identity matrix.
Figure imgf000018_0004
Figure imgf000019_0001
Now Z = DBτ(ξ -E(ξ)). So D(r)"1B(r)τ(ξ -E(ξ)) = Z(r) (ignoring the last M-r equations because Zr+i = ... = ZM = 0).
Figure imgf000019_0002
Now each λj is the eigenvalue of cov(ξ,ξ) corresponding to the eigenvector bj, and [b\, ... , bjyj} is an orthonormal basis of RM. So we have λj = Qcov(ξ,ξ)(°i) f°r j = 1, ... , M, where Qcov(ξ,ξ) *s me quadratic form associated with the matrix cov(ξ,ξ). But λj = 0, for j = r+1, ... , M, so that bjT(ξ -E(ξ)) = 0 a.e. for j = r+1, ... ,
M. Therefore we ha ξ- E{ξ)) = 0 a.e..
Thus we have (&|A
Figure imgf000019_0003
D(r)z{r) and (br+1|Λ % J {ξ - E{ξ)) = 0 a.e..
Therefore (b, | A \br Jξ = (b, | A \br f E{ξ) + D(r)z(r) and
Figure imgf000019_0004
\bM f ξ =
Figure imgf000019_0005
\bM E {ξ) a.e..
Given that (&r+1 |Λ \bM J ξ = (*r+1 |Λ \bM J E{ξ) a.e., we make the assumption of consistency that
Figure imgf000019_0006
We now show that {ξ = x <≠> B(rf ξ = B(rf x) a.e.. It is clear that ξ = x => B{rf ξ = B(rf x . So suppose thati?(r)r ξ = B(r)T x .
Figure imgf000019_0007
But B(r)τ ξ = B(r) x by hypothesis, (*r+1 |Λ \bM f ξ
Figure imgf000019_0008
\bM )τ E(ξ) a.e. and (br+ι|A
Figure imgf000019_0009
) E{ξ) = (br+1|A \bM ) x by the assumption of consistency.
Figure imgf000020_0001
But Bis orthogonal. Therefore ξ = x a.e.. So we have shown that B(rf ξ = B(rf x => (ξ = x a.e.) , which implies that \B(r)T ξ = B(r)τ x => = x) a.e.. Therefore (^ = * <=> #(r)r = B{rf x) a.e..
So we have (ξ - x <=> B(r)7" E( ) + £>(r)Z(r) = B{rf x) a.e.. Thus E(θ\ξ = x) = E(φ)(r)z(r) = 5(r)r( t- E( )))
Figure imgf000020_0002
Now Ε(Z(r)) = 0 and cov(Z(r),Z(r)) = Ir which is non-singular.
So, by the Theorem on Normal Correlation we have
Figure imgf000020_0003
= E(θ) + cov(0, Z{r))D{rY B(r)τ {x - E(ξ)) .
Figure imgf000020_0004
= E{θ) + c v{θ,Z{r))D{r)-lB{r)τ{x- E{ξ)) = E(θ) + cov(tf, (r)"15(r)r (# - £(«))D(rr B{r)τ (x - E[ξ)) = E{θ) + cov(0, - Eiξ rWf1 D(r)"12?(r)r (* - E(f ))
Figure imgf000020_0005
We now define
Figure imgf000020_0006
Referring to Figure 2, E(#| = x) is calculated 54.
Then we get E(θ\ξ = x) = E(ø) + cov(0, )cov(£ ξf {x - E{ξ)) . E{θ) + cov(0, )cσv(£ ξf (x - E{ξ)) .
We also have
Figure imgf000020_0007
(r)-1 B{r)τ [x - E{ξ)))
Figure imgf000021_0001
= cov(0, θ)-cov{θ, Z(r))cov(z(r), Z(r))-1 cov(0, Z(r))r
(by the Theorem on Normal Correlation) = cov{θ,θ)- cov(0, Z(r))/r cov(#, Z(r))r
Figure imgf000021_0002
= cov(#, θ) - cov(#, D(rY B{rf )cov(#, E>(r)_1 B(rf ξf = cov(#, θ) - cov(0, ξ)B(r)D(r)"1 D{r)~l B{rf cov(#, ξf = cov{θ,θ)-cov{θ,ξ)cov{ξ,ξf cov{θ,ξf .
Referring to Figure 2, cov(#,#| = x) is calculated 54.
Thus we have
Figure imgf000021_0003
= x)= cov(θ,θ)-cov(θ,ξ)cov(ξ,ξf cov(θ,ξf . Note that if r = 0, we have E(θ\ξ = x)= E(θ) and
Figure imgf000021_0004
cov(θ,θ) .
Figure imgf000021_0005
Note that the construction of cov(^,^) does not depend on the normality of ξ. If cov( , ) is non-singular, one can show that cov(ξ,ξf = cov(ξ,ξ)~l . One can also show that the value of cov( , ξ) is independent of the choice and ordering of the members of the basis of eigenvectors of cov( , ξ) . These facts are proved later. Note also that the derivation of the formulae for
Figure imgf000022_0001
= x) and
Figure imgf000022_0002
= x) only
depends on the normality of and not on our interpretation of θ and ξ as unknown
Figure imgf000022_0003
and known rate changes, respectively.
We now give a slight generalisation of Theorem 3.3.4 of Y.L.Tong, The Multivariate Normal Distribution. Springer :
Suppose that is unconditionally normal where ξ and θ are random vectors in R M θ and RN, respectively. Let x e RM. Then θ, conditional on ξ = x, is normally distributed.
Proof
First suppose that is non-singular.
Let A be any M by N real matrix and define φA
Figure imgf000022_0004
Figure imgf000022_0007
Then 9A: RM → RN is non-singular, φ = φ_A and detføΛ ) = det(/ )det(/Λr ) = 1 .
But ψA non-singular and non-singular normal imply that
Figure imgf000022_0005
is also non-singular normal.
Figure imgf000022_0006
We have ξ' = ξ and θ' = Aξ + θ. Then E(ξ') = E(ξ),
E(θ') = AE(ξ) + E(θ), cov(ξ', ξ') = cov(ξ, ξ), cov(θ', θ') = cov(Aξ+θ, Aξ+Θ), = cov(Aξ, Aξ) + cov(Aξ, θ) + cov(θ, Aξ) + cov(θ, θ) = Acov(ξ, ξ)Aτ + Acov(ξ, θ) + cov(θ, ξ)Aτ + cov(θ, θ), and cov(θ', ξ') (= cov(ξ', θ')τ )
= cov(Aξ, ξ) + cov(θ, ξ) = Acov(ξ, ξ) + cov(θ, ξ). We can now choose A to ensure that cov(θ', ξ') = 0. Thus we require Acov(ξ, ξ) + cov(θ, ξ) = 0, so that A = -cov(θ, ξ)cov(ξ, ξ)"1 (ξ is non-singular). df ' ' -cov(θ,ξ)cov{ξ,ξ)
Figure imgf000023_0001
df where g(x1,x2)=x2 - cov(#, )cov( , ξ) xx , for xi e RM and x2 e RN.
Then cov(ξ,g(ξ, θ)) = 0. But ξ and g(ξ,θ) are normal because is normal.
fX\
Now ψ is non-singular and is non-singular normal. ΘJ
So is non-singular normal.
Figure imgf000023_0002
Therefore the distribution function of is absolutely continuous.
Figure imgf000023_0003
Notation
Let Fx denote the distribution function of X and fx the density function of X, for any random variable X.
Then we have
Figure imgf000023_0004
for i e RM and x2 e RN, where mi is M-dimensional Lebesgue measure and m2 is N- dimensional Lebesgue measure.
Now
Figure imgf000024_0001
because det(ψ) = 1.
We also have
Figure imgf000024_0002
So
Figure imgf000025_0001
Thus we have / ,~ = f,~ oψ 1.
Θ [ø Now we also have det(^_1 ) 1 (the absolute value of the determinant of the Jacobian of ψ"1)
= M 1}
1 ~ detfør)
= 1. Thus
fΛ W mldm
Figure imgf000025_0002
Figure imgf000025_0003
(by a change of variable)
Figure imgf000025_0004
ov(ξ,ξ) 1x
Figure imgf000026_0001
1] >
= Fθ (x2 + cov(#, )cov(£ ξfλ x \ξ = x )Fξ [x ) .
Figure imgf000026_0002
because ξ and g(ξ, θ) are independent. Thus
Fθ (x2 + ∞v{θ, ξ)∞v(ξ, ξ)~l x, \ξ = xx )Fξ (X, ) = g(w) (x2 )F# (*, ) , for all i e RM and all x2 e RN.
But ξ is non-singular, so that Fξ (xx ) > 0 for all xi e R >Mλ
Thus Fθ
Figure imgf000026_0003
) for all i and x2.
Figure imgf000026_0004
Then Fθ (x2 + cov(#, ξ)cov{ξ, ξ)~l x\ξ = x)= Fg{ξβ) (x2 ) for all x2 e RN.
But g(ξ,θ) is normal and cov(ξ,θ )cov(ξ,ξ)_1x e RN is a constant. Therefore the distribution of θ, conditional on ξ = x, is normal.
Now suppose that (ξ) is singular.
Put Mx .
Figure imgf000026_0005
Then there exist x'e R , random vectors ξ' and θ' of dimension Mi and Ni respectively, an M by Mi matrix A, an N by Mi matrix Bi and an N by Ni matrix B2
is non-singular
Figure imgf000026_0006
f \ normal. Because is non-singular normal, θ', conditional on ξ' = x', is normally
\β j distributed. But when ξ' = x', we have θ = Bi ' + B2θ' a.e., where Bix' is constant and θ' is normal. Thus θ, conditional on ξ' = x', is an affine function of a normally distributed random vector and is therefore normal. But (ξ'= O ξ = x) a.e. Therefore θ, conditional on ξ = x, is normally distributed.
Let us now return to our interpretation of ξ and θ as known and unknown rate changes. We have shown that θ, conditional on ξ = x, is
Figure imgf000027_0001
Now (covfe , θv \ξ =
Figure imgf000027_0003
.
Figure imgf000027_0002
. JAJ) _ Ω
For Δφ unknown, let oty e { 1, ... , N} be its index in θ, so that ^ c °&
Conditional Distributions of Rate Changes
For each unknown Δ , we have E[Aψ \ξ = x j = Eψ ξ ~ x) and
var(Δφ \ξ = xj-
Figure imgf000027_0004
Δ , conditional on ξ = x, is
Figure imgf000027_0005
= xjj. For each known Δφ , let
Figure imgf000027_0006
be the known value of
Δ . Then
Figure imgf000027_0007
and var(Δφ| = x)= 0 , so that Δφ , conditional on ξ =
x, is N(x,U) ,θ) . Thus we know
Figure imgf000027_0008
= x) and cov(Δφ \ξ = x) for all Δφ (and Aψ is normally distributed). Now, for every pair ( Δ, 5 Δ - ), we have
ΔΦ} is known otherwise
Figure imgf000027_0009
Then, for any j and i < i , we can calculate the conditional mean of a rate change :
Figure imgf000027_0010
and the conditional variance of a rate change : varfe ,| = = x)
Figure imgf000028_0001
Thus Aψ., , conditional on ξ= x, is
Figure imgf000028_0002
We can also calculate the conditional covariance of a pair of rate changes :
Figure imgf000028_0003
and the conditional correlation of a pair of rate changes :
Figure imgf000028_0004
provided that var^Δ^1^ \ξ = x)> 0 and var(Δ(^ , \ξ = x)> 0 We can clearly also calculate the conditional multivariate normal distribution of any vector of rate changes.
We will make use of the following well-known result : Lemma
1 2 If X ~ N(μ,σ2), then E(e ) = %" and var(ex) = e2/t+σ2 (eσ' -1) ,
Proof
We use integration by substitution.
Figure imgf000028_0005
df χ — β Let us make the substitution y = — - σ . Then : dx σ
Figure imgf000029_0001
1 2
= e z
Now put Y = ex , so that F2 = e 2X
2 +^
But 2X ~ N(2μ,4σ2) , so that E(72) = e M~ = e2iμ+<χ2) .
Then var(ex ) = var(F) = E(F2) - (E(F))2 = e2{μ+σ2) - e μ^ = e2μ+<j2 (eσ* - 1) .
Marginal Distributions of Rates 30
Let φ be a condition expressing the fact that the known rates take their known values.
Then
Figure imgf000029_0002
\ξ = x), and so on. We
wish to calculate the distribution of Rt J , conditional on φ, for each unknown
Rt J where j e {l,...,m} and i e {θ,l,...,n}. Let 7* e {l,...,rn}. We suppose that Rtk } is known for some k.
forward calculation
Suppose Rt J is not known and Rtk 3 is known for some k < i, and Rta J is not known for k < α < i.
case R0) BM
Figure imgf000029_0003
Then RlJ) , conditional on φ, is
Figure imgf000030_0001
case Rω GBM
Figure imgf000030_0002
Then In (R,^), conditional on φ, is
Figure imgf000030_0003
If we put μ = Π(R^ )+ E(A | ξ = x) and σ2 = var(Δ(^_. | ξ = x) , we also
have #(Rt ω 1 φ) = +^~ and var(R,ω | φ) = e 2"+σ2 (^ - 1) .
backward calculation
Suppose Rt.} is not known and tk is known for some k > i, and Rt(χ is not known for i < α < k.
caseRωBM πO") _ τf) /if)
We have
Figure imgf000030_0004
, so that -*£ ~ i .
Then Rt' , conditional on φ, is $? -^fe = *), valfe ξ = x))
case R0) GBM
Figure imgf000030_0005
Thenln(R( ( )), conditional on φ, is
Figure imgf000030_0006
*)) If we put μ = ln(R,j) )- E(A \ ξ = x) and σ2 = var(Δ( f^ | ξ = x) , we also
have E(RiJ) I φ) = eμ+τ and var(R< j) | ) = e2μ+σ2 (e°2 - 1) .
Filling the unknown rates 56
We now give three methods of filling the unknown rates. Using the first method, we fill the unknown rates in such a way that the rate changes take their expected values conditional on φ. This method is equivalent to filling the unknown rates with their conditional modes (conditional on φ). Using the second method, we fill the unknown rates with their expected values conditional on φ. Using the third method, we simulate the unknown rates conditional on φ. In each case, we suppose that, for each j, R^ is
known for some k. For each unknown rate R' , we will let βU denote its filled
value.
Method 1 : Expected Rate Changes 31
We set each unknown Δφ to E Aψ \ξ = x) and "back out" the unknown rates. forward calculation
Suppose RU) is not known and "^ is known for some k < i, and Rta s not
known for k < < i.
case Rφ BM
Figure imgf000031_0001
case Rφ GBM
Figure imgf000032_0001
backward calculation
Suppose Rtp is not known and R k is known for some k > i, and Rta s not known for i < α < k.
case Rq) BM
Figure imgf000032_0002
so that ^>=^- ^H. case Rω GBM
Figure imgf000032_0003
Method 2 : Expected Rates 32
We take RU = £(RΦ ø>) for each unknown rate R, . forward calculation
Suppose Rj is not known and Rtk is known for some k < i, and Rt(χ is not known for k < < i.
case Rα) BM τfj _ τfJ) — J&J) τfj) _ τti) i df)
We have Λ, ~ ,ti , so that ^ ~ '+" ^.
Figure imgf000033_0001
case Rq) GBM
Figure imgf000033_0002
Theni? (/) = E(R^e (Δ^ι^)
Figure imgf000033_0003
= Λjo exp(E(Δ( ( ,£ι |p)+ 1 varfe \φ])
= R? exp(Efe = x)+ 1 varfe |# = x)) .
backward calculation
Suppose Rt J is not known and Rtk is known for some k > i, and Rt is not known for i < α < k.
case Rq) BM
Figure imgf000034_0001
τfJ) — D ") __/ ) so that i ~ ^ ^ t.
Then ^ω = Eitfty) = R^ - ε(Aψ \ξ = x).
case R0) GBM
Figure imgf000034_0002
Method 3 : Simulated Rates 33
The approach here is to take a random drawing θ from N(E((|< =
Figure imgf000034_0003
= x)) which, together with the known rates, then determines j ) for each unknown rate
Rt { . There is an orthonormal basis {slsK ,5^} of Rw consisting of eigenvectors of
Figure imgf000034_0004
= x). Say sy ) = (sy )(;>;
Figure imgf000034_0005
Then S is orthogonal and where ; is the
Figure imgf000034_0006
eigenvalue of cov(#,#| = x) corresponding to the eigenvector s , for 7 = 1, ,N.
Without loss of generality, there is a unique t such that O≤t≤N and μx≥μ2≥K≥μt>0 and μ3 = 0 for j = t + 1,K , N (reordering the columns of B and renaming the
If t = 0 , we have
Figure imgf000034_0007
= x).
So suppose that t > 0. Let η ~
Figure imgf000035_0001
= x)). We can think of η as "θ conditional on ξ =x" . Let * ( ) and cov* ( , ) denote the expectation and covariance operators, respectively, arising out of the conditional distribution
Figure imgf000035_0002
- x),cov(#,#| = x)) . Then we have E * (77) =
Figure imgf000035_0003
= x) and cov* (77, η) = cov(ι , θ\ξ = x) .
Put Δ Δ*S1(η -E*(η)).
Figure imgf000035_0004
Figure imgf000035_0005
so that Wj = 0 for j = t+1, ... , N.
Thus Wi,...,Wt are uncorrelated N(0,1) and therefore independent.
Figure imgf000035_0006
Now W = A*Sτ{η-ε* (η)) implies that Δ(t)-1S(t)r(;7-E * (77)) = W(t), so that S(t)r {η-ε * (77)) = A(t)W (t) . We also have (y,+1 |K \sN J{η - E* (77)) = 0 a.e..
But S(t) = (j, |K \st ) . Thus we have Sr (77 - E * (77)) = a.e.
Figure imgf000035_0007
Then 77 = E* (77)+ SI Δ(t tJ a.e., because S is orthogonal.
0 Let WX,K ,Wt be uncorrelated drawings from N(0,1). Then
M
§ = ε(θ\ξ = x)+ s M~Wt can be taken to be a random drawing from 0
Figure imgf000036_0001
So we have shown how to take a random drawing θ from N(E(θ\ξ = x),cov(#,ø| = x)) for t=0 and for t>0.
For Δφ unknown, we can now take its simulated value, Δφ , to be "av . Finally, we use these Δφ to derive simulated values of the unknown rates :
forward calculation
Suppose
Figure imgf000036_0002
is known for some k<i and
Figure imgf000036_0003
is not known for k<α<i.
case Rω BM
We require fiM -^ = ΫI a =k+l
Figure imgf000036_0004
case Rφ GBM
We require
Figure imgf000036_0005
Figure imgf000036_0006
backward calculation
Figure imgf000037_0001
Suppose j- is not known and . is known for some k>i and ιa is not known for i<α<k.
case Rω BM
We requi .re p-
Figure imgf000037_0002
Figure imgf000037_0003
case Rφ GBM
Figure imgf000037_0004
Singularity and the Assumption of Consistency
It is possible to get anomalous results if the known rate changes are not consistent with the dependence relations, obtaining almost everywhere, that are implied by the unconditional rate dynamics, that is, if the assumption of consistency
Figure imgf000037_0005
f x = (br+1
Figure imgf000037_0006
f ε{ξ) is not satisfied. This assumption of consistency can only fail to be satisfied if cov( , ) is singular. How can one guarantee that cov( , ) is non-singular ? cov( ,^) is certainly non-singular if the unconditional covariance matrix of rate changes per unit interval of time for all the rate series in question is non-singular. But we can weaken this condition. One can show that if the unconditional covariance matrix of rate changes per unit interval of time for the rate series for which there are known rate changes (runs of length greater than or equal to one) is non-singular, then cov(< , ) is also non-singular, so that the assumption of consistency is necessarily satisfied. Note that this is a sufficient, but not a necessary, condition for the assumption of consistency to be satisfied.
Worked Example
We give an example with two rate series and two time intervals because we wish to illustrate correlation effects across rate series and across time intervals. We will give calculated values rounded to six decimal places.
Let the rate series be R(I and R(2) , so that m, the number of rate series, is 2. We first specify the unconditional rate dynamics.
We suppose that R(1) is a Geometric Brownian Motion and R( ) is a Brownian Motion.
Let the unconditional mean vector, μ, be and the unconditional volatility vector,
Figure imgf000038_0001
σ, be These are both expressed per unit interval of time. Let the unconditional
Figure imgf000038_0002
correlation matrix, . Then the unconditional covariance
Figure imgf000038_0003
matrix per unit interval of time,
Figure imgf000038_0004
We now specify the incomplete rate data.
We take n, the number of time intervals, to be 2. We consider three times t0 = 0 , df df t! = 1 and t2 = 2. Then Δtj =tλ -t0 = 1 and Δt2 =t2 ~tλ = 1.
We put R asterisks denote
Figure imgf000038_0005
unknown rates. That is, we suppose that R^ = 1 , R = 2 , R^2) = V/2 and R[ = 1 and that Rx m and R2 are unknown. We put
Figure imgf000039_0001
φ expresses what is known about the rate values.
We now determine the runs ζ and the unknown rate changes θ. We have two runs :
Figure imgf000039_0002
So we take , so that ξ = A + Δ( 2 } and ξ2 = Aψ , and we will apply
Figure imgf000039_0003
the conditioning ξ = x where condition ξ ~ x
Figure imgf000039_0004
expresses the fact that the known rate changes take their known values.
df
We have M = dim( ) = 2
We put , the matrix of rate changes over time intervals determined by
Figure imgf000039_0005
successive points of time. Then Δ , because Δφ = -/2 and A , Δ^ and
Δφ are unknown. Note that Δ does not contain information about runs of length > 2.
We also put of unknown rate changes over time intervals
Figure imgf000039_0006
determined by successive points in time. Then θx = A , θ2 = Δ2 } and θ3 = Δ2 2) .
Let us calculate cov( , ) .
We have cov( , ) = COV(Δ( 1 1) + A , A + Aψ ) = Atxσ2 + At2σ2 (Aψ and Δ^ are independent)
Figure imgf000040_0001
= cov(Δ?,Δ( 1 2)) (Δ( 2 } and Aψ are independent)
= Δtj/£"12
and cov(£,f2) = cov(Δφ,Δφ)
: Δt^2
1,
Figure imgf000040_0002
Let us now decompose cov( ,^) .
0.382683"
If we take bγ
0.923880
Figure imgf000040_0003
df
A =1.103553
and A=0-396447 > then {b b2} is an orthonormal basis of eigenvectors of cov(<, ) with corresponding df eigenvalues A>A satisfying ≥A >0, so that r = rank(cov(ξ,ξ))=2. Note that we are not showing the working for this decomposition of cov(ξ,ζ) : standard techniques exist for computing an orthonormal basis of eigenvectors of a real symmetric matrix and the associated eigenvalues.
Note that cov( , ) is non-singular, so that the assumption of consistency is satisfied. 04
40
Figure imgf000041_0001
We now
Figure imgf000041_0002
= x) and
Figure imgf000041_0003
= x) .
Figure imgf000041_0004
(Δ ,Δ«) covfΔΪ ?) cov(Δ ,Δφ)' cov ilβ,θ) = covΔW.Δ?) cov(Δ«,Δ«) COV(Δ» Δ?>) cov'(Δφ,Δ«) cov(Δφ,Δ«) cov(Δφ,Δφ)
and cov ile,ξ)
Figure imgf000041_0005
o
PA o so that
Figure imgf000042_0001
and cov(ø, θ\ξ = x) = cov(ι , θ) - cov(0, #)cov(£ ξf cov(0, ξ)
Figure imgf000042_0002
Note that E(Δ( 1 1) \ξ = x)+ E(A \ξ = x)
Figure imgf000042_0003
= 0.368492+ 0.324656
= 0.693148-7 (correcting for the round-off error)
= ln(2)
= Δ«
Figure imgf000042_0004
Distribution of Rate Changes
Figure imgf000042_0005
Δ , conditional on = x ,
Figure imgf000042_0006
(f ε(θ ξ = xj\ fcov(θxx\ξ = x) covfø ,θ3\ξ = x)
Figure imgf000042_0007
(f 0.368492 ( 0.107143 -0.107143ΪΪ
= N w -0.675344 -0.107143 0.857143 J We can also compute the conditional correlation coefficient of Δ^ and Δ( 2 } :
Figure imgf000043_0001
-0.107143 ~ V0.107143V0.857143
= -0.353554.
This is a non-zero correlation across the two rate series and across the two time intervals. Note that the Brownian Motion assumption implies that the unconditional correlation coefficient, p[Af ,A ), is zero.
Marginal Rate Distributions
The unknown rates are R] (1) and R2 2) .
We can use a backward calculation for Rj (1) since Rψ is known.
Now R(1) is a GBM.
Then ln(R! (1)) , conditional on φ,
~ N(ln(Rφ ) - ε(Af2 \ ξ = x), vax(A \ ξ = x))
= N(ln(2) - E(Δ( 2 υ I ξ = x), var(Δ( 2 1) | ξ = x)) = N(ln(2) - (θ2 \ ξ = x), coγ(θ22 \ ξ = xj)
= N(0.368492,0.107143). Thus ln(R! (1 ) is normally distributed with an expected value of 0.368492 and a variance of 0.107143.
We must use a forward calculation for R2 2) because Rj (2) is the only known rate for R(2) . Now R(2) is a Brownian Motion. Then Rψ , conditional on φ ,
~ Nfe(2) + E(Aψ I ξ = x), var(Δ<g \ξ = x))
= N{l + E(θ3\ξ = x),cov(θ33\ξ = x))
= N(0.324656,0.857143). Thus R2 2 is normally distributed with an expected value of 0.324656 and a variance of 0.857143.
Filling the Unknown Rates
Method 1 : Expected Rate Changes
The filled value of Rφ is: Rφ = Rφ exp(-E(Δ( ! υ 2 \ξ = x))
= 2exV(-E(θ2\ξ = x)) = 2 exp(- 0.324656) = 1.445553.
The filled value of R{) is :
Figure imgf000044_0001
= 1+ Ε(03| = x)
= 1-0.647344 = 0.324656.
Method 2 : Expected Rates
The filled value of Rφ is :
Figure imgf000045_0001
Rψ ex (-E(Δ« \ξ = x)+±v*r(A% \ξ = x))
2exp (- E(θ21 ξ = x) + cov(θ22\ξ = x))
2exp (-0.324656+^0.107143)
1.525105.
The filled value of Rψ is
R (2) = E(R \φ)
= R +ε(Aψ\ξ = x)
= 0.324656.
Method 3 : Simulated Rates
We first decompose cov(#, θ\ξ = x) . f-0.154488Λ
If we take sx = 0.154488 0.975892
Figure imgf000045_0002
μx =0.891067, μ2 =0.180362 and /3=0, 45
then {sx , s2 , s3 } is an orthonormal basis of eigenvectors of cov(#, θ\ξ = x) with corresponding eigenvalues μi, μ2, μ3 and μi > μ2> μ3 =0.
Then t = rank(cov(θ, θ\ξ = x)) = 2.
Figure imgf000046_0001
Let us just do one simulation.
Let Wx = 0.065137 and W2 = -0.617774 be independent random drawings from
N(0,1), the standard normal distribution.
Figure imgf000046_0002
Now take Aψ =θx = 0.540029 ,
Aψ = §2 = 0.153118 and Δ(2)3 = -0.558022. Note that Aψ + Δ( 2 υ = ln(2) = Aψ2 = Aψ + Δ( 2 . We can then take the simulated value of Rφ to be :
Figure imgf000046_0003
= 2 exp(- Δ2 1)) = 1.716057
Figure imgf000046_0004
and the simulated value of R2 2) to be :
Figure imgf000046_0005
= 0.441978.
Detecting Extreme Rates Suppose that we are given (complete or incomplete) rate data together with the unconditional rate dynamics of the rate series concerned. Let K be the set of known rates. For each rate x belonging to K, let us use x to denote the rate considered as a random variable and let [x] denote the known value. Let K0 be a subset, possibly empty, of K that consists of the known rates whose values are to be accepted without question. We wish to- partition K \ KQ into two sets, E and N, such that, for each x e E , [x] is extreme relative to the values of the known rates in K0 N , and, for each x e N , [x] is not extreme relative to the values of the known rates in 0 u JV
Figure imgf000047_0001
The idea is that the values of the extreme rates, that is, those belonging to E, are to be considered potentially spurious.
For simplicity, we will use a two-sided confidence interval, centred on the mean, for x if the rate series to which x belongs is a Brownian Motion (or is normally distributed) and a two-sided confidence interval, centred on the mean, for ln(x) if the rate series to which x belongs is a Geometric Brownian Motion (or is lognormally distributed). Note that other confidence intervals could be used.
Suppose X c K and g X .
If the rate series to which x belongs is a Brownian Motion (or is normally distributed), let μ(x, X) be the mean of x conditional on the known rates in X (taking their known values), let σ(x,X) be the standard deviation of x conditional on the known rates in
X, and put
Figure imgf000047_0002
0 <τ(x, Z) = 0 Λ [x] = t(x, Z)
+ ∞ otherwise.
If the rate series to which x belongs is a Geometric Brownian Motion (or is lognormally distributed), let μ(x,X) be the mean of ln(x) conditional on the known rates in X, let σ(x,X) be the standard deviation of ln(x) conditional on the known rates in X, and put
Figure imgf000047_0003
0 σ(x, X) = 0 Λ ln([x]) = μ(x, X)
+ ∞ otherwise.
Note that μ(x,X) and σ(x,X) depend on calculated conditional rate dynamics. Note also that η(x,X) is the distance, measured in standard deviations, of the known value of x from the conditional mode of x.
Now let p e [0,1] be some nominated confidence level. df We define φ(x,X,p) = false if X contains no known rate for the rate series to which x belongs f p „Λ + Λ 1\ η(x,X)>N~ otherwise
V 2 j
"the value of x is extreme relative to the known rates in X", where N_1 ( ) is the inverse of the cumulative normal distribution function.
One can use the following algorithm to determine the sets E and Ν : E -0
Figure imgf000048_0001
repeat
{ if { e N \ K01 φ(x,N \ {x}, p)} ≠ 0
{
II exclude the most extreme rate choose x e N \ K0 such that 77(x,Ν\{x}) = sup{77(y,Ν\{y})| ye Ν\K0}
N<-N\{x}
Ε <-Ε {x}
// are some rates now misclassified as extreme ? repeat
{
(for each yeE)
(irf-. (y,N,ρ)
{
N -Nu{y} E <-E\{y} } ) } until E does not change
} } until E does not change
Note that the sets E and N are not uniquely determined. Modelling Zero Coupon Rate Series as a (Geometric) Brownian Motion
The modelling system 1 allows the modelling of the zero coupon rate curves of several bond issuers at several trading dates given a number of bond trades, where specified zero coupon rate series of the several issuers are assumed to follow a (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions.
For each issuer, a set of maturity buckets, that is, a set of disjoint intervals covering all maturities of interest, is specified. For each issuer and each maturity bucket, a representative or standard maturity falling in the maturity bucket is specified. For each issuer, a pricing function for bonds of the issuer and a method of interpolation for zero coupon rates of the issuer are specified. For each issuer and each standard maturity, the rate type, that is, the compounding frequency and the notional number of days in a year, of the standard maturity zero coupon rate series of the issuer is specified. These rate types may vary from one standard maturity to another for the same issuer. The standard maturity zero coupon rate series, of the specified rate types, of the several issuers are assumed to follow a Brownian Motion or a Geometric Brownian Motion, or a combination of the two, in several dimensions. This involves, first, specifying, for each standard maturity zero coupon rate series of each issuer, the parametric model type (Brownian Motion or Geometric Brownian Motion), the volatility (standard deviation of the rate changes) per unit interval of time and the mean of the rate changes per unit interval of time, and, second, specifying a correlation coefficient of the rate changes for each pair of standard maturity zero coupon rate series (not necessarily of the same issuer). The unit interval of time relative to which the parameters for the (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions are expressed can be measured as calendar time or as trading time. The assumption of a (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions together with its associated parameters can be described as the specification of the unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics.
A number of trading dates, not necessarily uniformly spaced, are specified. For each trading date, zero or more traded bonds are specified. This involves specifying, for each traded bond, the issuer of the bond, the settlement date, the maturity date, the annual coupon rate, the annual coupon frequency and the traded yield whose compounding frequency is taken to be the given annual coupon frequency. Note that a bond that traded on two dates is here treated as two traded bonds because of the two trading dates, the two settlement dates and the two traded yields. It is assumed that, for each issuer and each trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds (of the given issuer) that traded on the given trading date are distinct. The specification of the trading dates and the traded bonds can be described as the specification of the traded bond data.
A standard maturity zero coupon rate series for a given issuer is taken to be "known" at a given trading date if there is a traded bond whose issuer is the given issuer, whose trading date is the given trading date and whose maturity, calculated from the given trading date, falls in the maturity bucket associated with the standard maturity zero coupon rate series. A standard maturity zero coupon rate series for a given issuer is taken to be "unknown" at a given trading date if it is not "known" at the given trading date. It is assumed that each standard maturity zero coupon rate series is "known" at at least one trading date. Note that a standard maturity zero coupon rate series that is "known" at some trading date does not have its value, at the given trading date, known with any certainty. Both the "known" and the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates can be considered to be random.
The modelling method provides a way of estimating both the "known" and the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates, for all issuers, all standard maturities and all trading dates, and depends on both the assumed unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and the traded bond data. The modelling method employs an iterative technique for estimating the "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates and generates, for each issuer and each trading date, a zero coupon rate curve whose maturity points consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls.
The modelling of zero coupon curves involves the following steps :
Step 1
For each issuer and each trading date for which there is at least one "known" standard maturity zero coupon rate for the given issuer at the given trading date, a zero coupon rate curve is constructed whose maturity points consist of the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve. Each zero coupon rate curve is constructed in such a way that pricing the traded bonds, associated with the curve, from the curve is consistent with the traded bond data associated with the curve. The curves are thus calibrated against the traded bond data. The curve construction employs not only the yields of the traded bonds, but also the specified pricing function for bonds of the issuer associated with the curve in question and the specified method of interpolation for zero coupon rates for the same issuer. The constructed curves are calibrated against the traded bond data, but do not incorporate correlation effects (or, more precisely, covariance effects) across issuers and trading dates. The curves are used to provide initial estimates for the
"known" standard maturity zero coupon rates, and no interpolation is necessary to calculate these estimates from the curves. This step can be described as calculating initial estimates for the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Step 2
The "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates, for all issuers and all trading dates, are filled using the expected values of the standard maturity zero coupon rate changes conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates (for all issuers and all trading dates) taking the current estimates of their values. In an alternative version, the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates, for all issuers and all trading dates, are filled with their expected values conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates (for all issuers and all trading dates) taking the current estimates of their values. The filling relies on the modelling method of aspect one. The filled values then provide estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. This step can be described as estimating the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates, given estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Step 3
Given the current estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates, a zero coupon rate curve is constructed for each issuer and for each trading date. The maturity points of each curve consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls. These curves are constructed in such a way that, first, they are calibrated against the traded bond data and, second, the constructed zero coupon rates corresponding to "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are determined by the given estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. The constructed curves provide the next estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates, using the specified methods of interpolation, if need be. This step can be described as recalibrating the estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Steps 2 and 3 are repeated, as a pair of steps, until the successive estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates are equal (or, in practice, until the successive estimates are sufficiently close), that is, until convergence is reached. Note that the repeated execution of steps 2 and 3 allows the progressive incorporation of correlation effects across bond maturities, issuers and trading dates into the estimates of the "known" and
"unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. When (and if) convergence is reached, the most recent iterates of the curves constructed in step 3 can be taken to be reasonable proxies for the modes of the zero coupon rates conditional on the traded bond data or, in the alternative version, reasonable proxies for the expected values of the zero coupon curves conditional on the traded bond data. The generated zero coupon rate curves have two notable properties. First, the values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates determined by the generated zero coupon rate curves are consistent with the expected values of the standard maturity zero coupon rate changes conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates taking values determined by the generated curves, or, in the alternative version, the values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates determined by the generated curves are the expected values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rate taking values determined by the generated curves. This means that correlation effects across issuers, maturities and trading dates have been incorporated into the generated curves. Second, the generated curves are calibrated against the traded bond data. The two properties together justify taking the generated zero coupon rate curves to be reasonable proxies for the modes of the zero coupon rates conditional on the traded bond data or, in the alternative version, reasonable proxies for the expected values of the zero coupon curves conditional on the traded bond data.
The generated curves enable the pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, of bonds (of the several issuers) other than the specified traded bonds. Thus one can estimate the values of portfolios of bonds of the several issuers at the specified trading dates in a manner consistent with the traded bond data. Such estimated portfolio values incorporate correlation effects across the trading dates, as well as across maturities and across issuers.
Note that it is possible to include specified trading dates on which no specified traded bonds of any issuer traded. An example might be a future trading date. A further two steps allow the approximate simulation of the zero coupon rate curves and of the "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. The idea behind these two steps is that the values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates are largely determined by the traded bond data and the conditional variation is largely concentrated in the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Step 4
The "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are filled using simulated values conditional on the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates taking values that result from convergence after the repeated execution of steps 2 and 3, where the alternative version of step 2 is not used. This manner of filling relies on the modelling method of aspect one. This step can be described as simulating the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Step 5 Given the simulated values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates provided by step 4, a zero coupon rate curve is constructed for each issuer and for each trading date. The maturity points of each curve consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls. The curves are constructed in such a way that, first, they are calibrated against the traded bond data and, second, the constructed zero coupon rates corresponding to the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are determined by the simulated values provided by step 4. The constructed curves are simulated and are correlated in a manner consistent with both the assumed unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and the traded bond data. Simulated values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates can be derived from the simulated curves, using the specified methods of interpolation, if need be. This step can be described as simulating the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Steps 4 and 5 are repeated, as a pair of steps, to provide as many simulations of the calibrated zero coupon rate curves and of the associated "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates as is desired. These simulations are conditional on the traded bond data.
The simulated curves enable the pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, of bonds (of the several issuers) other than the specified traded bonds. Thus one can simulate the values of portfolios of bonds of the several issuers at the specified trading dates in a manner consistent with the traded bond data. Such simulations incorporate correlation effects across the trading dates, as well as across maturities and across issuers.
Modelling Zero Coupon Rate Spread Series as a (Geometric) Brownian Motion
The modelling system 1 allows the modelling of the zero coupon rate curves of several bond issuers at several trading dates given a number of bond trades, where specified zero coupon rate spread series of the several issuers are assumed to follow a (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions.
For each issuer, a set of maturity buckets is specified. It is assumed that the number of maturity buckets is the same for all issuers. For each issuer and each maturity bucket, a representative or standard maturity falling in the maturity bucket is specified.
The maturity buckets for each issuer are ordered in ascending order of the associated standard maturities. This ordering is used to set up a correspondence between the maturity buckets of any given issuer and those of any other issuer. The standard maturities for any given issuer would normally be chosen to be equal to the corresponding standard maturities for the other issuers.
For each issuer, a pricing function for bonds of the issuer and a method of interpolation for zero coupon rates of the issuer are specified. For each issuer and each standard maturity, the rate type, that is, the compounding frequency and the notional number of days in a year, of the standard maturity zero coupon rate series of the issuer is specified.
It is assumed that one of the issuers, the base issuer, is, at all times, of a strictly higher credit quality than the other issuers.
The standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series can be specified in one of two ways :
Firstly, the standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series for the base issuer are the standard maturity zero coupon rate series for the base issuer (one for each maturity bucket of the base issuer). For each of the remaining issuers and for each maturity bucket of the given issuer, there is a standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series defined to be the difference between the standard maturity zero coupon rate series associated with the given issuer and the given maturity bucket and the standard maturity zero coupon rate series associated with the base issuer and the maturity bucket, of the base issuer, that corresponds with the given maturity bucket. In this case, the specified standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series can be described as series of spreads over the base issuer. Secondly, it is assumed that the issuers are ordered in strictly descending order of credit quality, so that the base issuer is the first issuer. The standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series for the base issuer are the standard maturity zero coupon rate series for the base issuer (one for each maturity bucket of the base issuer). For each of the remaining issuers and for each maturity bucket of the given issuer, there is a standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series defined to be the difference between the standard maturity zero coupon rate series associated with the given issuer and the given maturity bucket and the standard maturity zero coupon rate series associated with the previous issuer and the maturity bucket, of the previous issuer, that corresponds with the given maturity bucket. In this case, the specified standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series can be described as series of successive spreads.
We can refer to the standard maturity zero coupon rate spread series as spread series. The spread series of the several issuers are assumed to follow a (Geometric)
Brownian Motion in several dimensions. This involves, first, specifying, for each spread series of each issuer, the parametric model type (Geometric Brownian Motion or Brownian Motion), the volatility (standard deviation of the spread changes) per unit interval of time and the mean of the spread changes per unit interval of time, and, second, specifying a correlation coefficient of the spread changes for each pair of spread series. The unit interval of time relative to which the parameters for the (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions are expressed can be measured as calendar time or as trading time.The assumption of a (Geometric) Brownian Motion in several dimensions together with its associated parameters can be described as the specification of the unconditional spread dynamics.
We will make the assumption that each spread series follows a Geometric Brownian Motion. This assumption ensures that spreads are positive. In the case of spreads over the base issuer, positive spreads reflect the assumption that the base issuer is, at all times, the issuer of highest credit quality. In Australia, the base issuer could be taken to be the Commonwealth of Australia. In the case of successive spreads, positive spreads reflect the assumption that the issuers are, at all times, strictly ordered by credit quality. Here, the term issuer can be interpreted to mean issuer class, for example, AAA or AA+, as defined by a ratings agency. Such issuer classes have a defined unchanging ordering by credit quality, whereas the relative credit quality of individual issuers can change over time.
A number of trading dates, not necessarily uniformly spaced, are specified. For each trading date, zero or more traded bonds are specified. This involves specifying, for each traded bond, the issuer of the bond, the settlement date, the maturity date, the annual coupon rate, the annual coupon frequency and the traded yield whose compounding frequency is taken to be the given annual coupon frequency. Note that a bond that traded on two dates is here treated as two traded bonds because of the two trading dates, the two settlement dates and the two traded yields. It is assumed that, for each issuer and each trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds, of the given issuer, that traded on the given trading date are distinct. The specification of the trading dates and the traded bonds can be described as the specification of the traded bond data.
A standard maturity zero coupon rate series for a given issuer is taken to be "known" at a given trading date if there is a traded bond whose issuer is the given issuer, whose trading date is the given trading date and whose maturity, calculated from the given trading date, falls in the maturity bucket associated with the standard maturity zero coupon rate series. A standard maturity zero coupon rate series for a given issuer is taken to be "unknown" at a given trading date if it is not "known" at the given trading date. These definitions of "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rate series induce natural definitions of "known" and "unknown" spread series, spreads and spread changes. It is assumed that each spread series is "known" at at least one trading date. A spread series that is "known" at some trading date does not have its value, at the given trading date, known with any certainty. Both the "known" and the "unknown" spreads, as well as the "known" and the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rate series, can be considered to be random.
The modelling method provides a way of estimating both the "known" and the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates (for all issuers, all standard maturities and all trading dates) and depends on both the assumed unconditional spread dynamics and the traded bond data. The modelling method employs an iterative technique for estimating the "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates and generates, for each issuer and each trading date, a zero coupon rate curve whose maturity points consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls.
The modelling method involves the following steps :
Step l
For each issuer and each trading date for which there is at least one "known" standard maturity zero coupon rate for the given issuer at the given trading date, a zero coupon rate curve is constructed whose maturity points consist of the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve. Each zero coupon rate curve is constructed in such a way that pricing the traded bonds, associated with the curve, from the curve is consistent with the traded bond data associated with the curve. The curves are thus calibrated against the traded bond data. The curve construction employs not only the yields of the traded bonds, but also the specified pricing function for bonds of the issuer associated with the curve in question and the specified method of interpolation for zero coupon rates for the same issuer. The constructed curves are calibrated against the traded bond data, but do not incorporate correlation effects across issuers and across trading dates. The curves are used to provide initial estimates for the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates, and no interpolation is necessary to calculate these estimates from the curves. This step can be described as calculating initial estimates for the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Step 2
The current estimates of the values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates induce current estimates of the values of the "known" spreads. One cannot simply fill the "unknown" spreads using the expected values of the spread changes conditional on the "known" spreads taking the current estimates of their values because passing from the current estimates of the values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates to the induced current estimates of the values of the "known" spreads involves loss of information. This loss of information can be repaired by adding a set of constraints that relate the "unknown" spreads to the current estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Each such constraint is linear in the "unknown" spreads. These constraints are, on the face of it, intractable because the assumed unconditional spread dynamics is expressed in terms of spread changes and not in terms of spreads. But the assumed unconditional spread dynamics and the assumption that each spread is "known" at at least one trading date enable the linear constraints to be transformed into non-linear constraints on the "unknown" spread changes. Each of these constraints can be expressed as an equation where the left hand side is a differentiable function of several "unknown" spread changes and the right hand side is a constant that depends on the current estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Now the problem is the non-linearity of the left hand sides of these constraint equations. The differentiability of the left hand sides enables affine approximations of the left hand sides to be calculated, given some estimate of the "unknown" spread changes. Assuming some estimate of the "unknown" spread changes, one can fill the "unknown" spreads using the expected values of the spread changes conditional both on the "known" spreads taking the current estimates of their values and on the linearised constraint equations being satisfied, where affine approximations of the left hand sides are used. These filled "unknown" spreads are not, in general, consistent with the current estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupoi rates. But the filled "unknown" spreads, combined with the current induced estimates of the values of the "known" spreads, can provide new estimates of the "unknown" spread changes that, in turn, can provide improved affine approximations of the left hand sides of the constraint equations. An iterative process is used to refine continuously the affine approximations until successive estimates of the filled "unknown" spreads are equal, that is. until convergence is reached. One can prove that, when convergence is reached, the filled "unknown" spreads are necessarily consistent with the current estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates. In particular, if the filled "unknown" spreads are taken as the values of the "unknown" spreads, then the linear constraints on the "unknown" spreads that were discussed earlier are satisfied exactly. One can then use the filled "unknown" spreads and the current estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates to derive the next estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. This step can be described as estimating the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates, given estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Step 3
Given the current estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates, a zero coupon rate curve is constructed for each issuer and trading date. The maturity points of each curve consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls. These curves are constructed in such a way that, first, they are calibrated against the traded bond data and, second, the constructed zero coupon rates corresponding to "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are determined by the given estimates of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. The constructed curves provide the next estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates, using the specified methods of interpolation, if need be. This step can be described as recalibrating the estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Steps 2 and 3 are repeated, as a pair of steps, until the successive estimates of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates are equal, that is, until convergence is reached. Note that the repeated execution of steps 2 and 3 allows the progressive incorporation of correlation effects across bond maturities, issuers and trading dates into the estimates of the "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. When convergence is reached, the most recent iterates of the curves constructed in step 3 can be taken to be reasonable proxies for the modes of the zero coupon rates conditional on the traded bond data. The generated zero coupon rate curves have two notable properties. First, the values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates determined by the generated zero coupon rate curves are consistent with the expected values of the spread changes conditional on the "known" spreads taking values determined by the generated zero coupon rate curves, where the calculation of the expected values is understood to rely on the affine approximations that result from step 2. This means that correlation effects across issuers, maturities and trading dates have been incorporated into the generated curves. Second, the generated curves are calibrated against the traded bond data. The two properties together justify taking the generated zero coupon rate curves to be reasonable proxies for the modes of the zero coupon curves rates conditional on the traded bond data.
The generated curves enable the pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, of bonds (of the several issuers) other than the specified traded bonds. Thus one can estimate the values of portfolios of bonds of the several issuers at the specified trading dates in a manner consistent with the traded bond data. Such estimated portfolio values incorporate correlation effects across the trading dates, as well as across maturities and issuers. Note that it is possible to include specified trading dates on which no specified traded bonds of any issuer traded. An example might be a future trading date.
A further two steps allow the approximate simulation of the zero coupon rate curves and of the "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. The idea behind these two steps is that the values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates are largely determined by the traded bond data and the conditional variation is largely concentrated in the "unknown" spreads. Note that the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates and the "unknown" spreads together determine the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Step 4
The "unknown" spreads are filled using simulated values conditional both on the "known" spreads taking the values that result from convergence after the repeated execution of steps 2 and 3 and on the linearised constraint equations, that also result from convergence, being satisfied. Note that, because of the affine approximations employed, the filled "unknown" spread values are not, in general, quite consistent with the values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates that result from convergence. One can use the values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates and the simulated values of the "unknown" spreads to derive simulated values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Because of the possible lack of consistency mentioned above, there is some latitude in the method of deriving the simulated values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates. This step can be described as simulating the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Step 5
Given the simulated values of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates provided by step 4, a zero coupon rate curve is constructed for each issuer and each trading date. The maturity points of each curve consist of, first, the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are those associated with the curve, and, second, the standard maturities for the maturity buckets, for the issuer associated with the curve, in which the maturity of no traded bond, whose issuer and trading date are those associated with the curve, falls. The curves are constructed in such a way that, first, they are calibrated against the traded bond data and, second, the constructed zero coupon rates corresponding to the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates are determined by the simulated values provided by step 4. The constructed curves are simulated and are correlated in a manner consistent with both the assumed unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and the traded bond data. Simulated values of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates can be derived from the simulated curves, using the specified methods of interpolation, if need be. This step can be described as simulating the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Steps 4 and 5 are repeated, as a pair of steps, to provide as many simulations of the calibrated zero coupon rate curves and of the associated "known" and "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates as is desired. These simulations are conditional on the traded bond data.
The simulated curves enable the pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, of bonds (of the several issuers) other than the specified traded bonds. Thus one can simulate the values of portfolios of bonds of the several issuers at the specified trading dates in a manner consistent with the traded bond data. Such simulations incorporate correlation effects across the trading dates, as well as across maturities and issuers.
In the technical description that follows, it is noted that the assumption is made that the multiplication of an undefined term by zero is equal to zero.
Technical Description : Modelling Bond Curves
Let P(y) be the total price of a given bond as a function of the bond's yield-to-maturity, quoted on some trading date. Note that it is possible to use different bond pricing functions for different bond issuers or even for different bonds of a given issuer. By way of example, let us give the following generalisation of the Reserve Bank of Australia's pricing formula for government bonds :
* J dHPod"-1 + Z(1 - d») - Cχ{m < EXDAYS}) if TI > 1
P\V) — Fo+CX{m > BXDAYS -t -, 1+ym/B lf n = l where : n is the number of coupon dates remaining after settlement (so that n - 1 whole coupon periods remain unless settlement occurs on a coupon date), y is the yield-to-maturity, expressed as a decimal, df f 1 if ψ is true - , , χM = 0 otherwise ' f°r any boolean expression φ,
Po is the face value of the bond,
F is the annual coupon frequency (a divisor of 12), m is the number of days from settlement to the next coupon date (after settlement),
M is the number of days from the last coupon date on or before settlement to the next coupon date (after settlement),
/ = m/M, the fraction of the current coupon period remaining, d = 1/(1 + y/F), the discount factor per coupon period,
C = PoGoupon/F, the normal coupon payment,
Coupon is the coupon rate of the bond, expressed as a decimal, and EXDAYS is the length of the ex coupon period in days.
This formula uses bill pricing if settlement falls in the last coupon period. If settlement does not fall in the last coupon period, we have n
P(y) = d^Pod"-1 + C(χ{m > BXDAYS} + ∑#~1))
3=2
If we are given a total bond price P, we can calculate a bond's implied yield by solving the equation P(y) = P numerically for y. There is, in general, no ; analytical method of calculating implied yields.
Figure imgf000063_0001
Let X represent an interpolation function : for a given maturity τ in days and a given 2;ero coupon rate curve C, Z(τ, C) will represent the interpolated continuously compounding zero coupon rate of maturity r. Note that it is possible to use different interpolation functions for different issuers.
We can price a given bond from a given curve C :
P(y) = e^o,C)ro B ^-X^fi^/B χ. i=ι and solve numerically for the yield-to-maturity y, where :
To > 0 is the maturity in days of the settlement of the bond,
B is the notional number of days in a year, and
((τj, Xj))j=χ v is the schedule of remaining cash-flows of the bond
Figure imgf000064_0001
Note that the schedule of cash-flows takes account of ex coupon periods. Note also that the notional number of days in a year could here be different from the notional number of days in a year that figures in the bond pricing function.
Now let C = ((SJ, rj))j-ι,...,n be a curve for some trading date and let y be the known yield of a bond whose maturity is r days from the given trading date. We suppose that r > sn if n > 1 and r > 0 if n — 0. We now show how to add to C a maturity point corresponding to r in a way that is consistent with the yield y. For x G ffi., let C[(τ, x)] be C U {(T, X)}. We can solve the equation
V
P{y) = e I('-o**«/B e- il C[M])'-i . j=l numerically for x, where, as before, ((TJ , XJ))J=I v is the schedule of cash-flows of the bond and TQ > 0 is the maturity in days of the bond's settlement which is assumed to be no earlier than the given trading date. Let x = r(y, C) be the solution. Then the bond's yield implied by the curve C U {(r, r(y, C))} is y, so that the extended curve C U {(τ, r(y,C))} is calibrated against the given yield y.
We now suppose that we have K > 1 issuers, indexed by k = 1, . . . , K. We can associate, with each issuer k, a bond pricing function tø, a notional number of days in a year B^ and an interpolation function X^ . For each issuer k, we suppose that we have a family, (Bm )mβW x oi βW > 1 maturity buckets, where, for each G {1, . . . ,β^}, Bm is a closed interval [a}n , bm ] for some α , ^' e N satisfying αjfc) = 1 and a = b^ + 1 for m = 2, . . . , /?(*) . Then, βw for each k, we have U B 0 N = {1, . . . , &$&,} and m B$ U B<#) = 0 for m=l distinct m, m' € {1, . .. , β^}. We will assume that, for each k, b h) is greater than or equal to the longest maturity (in days) of the bonds of issuer k with which we will be concerned.
We assume that we have N + 1 trading dates DQ, . . . , DN of interest where N > 0 and DQ < . . . < DN. We also assume that we have N + 1 associated times to ■ ■ ■ , t/v. The unit of time for the times to, ■ ■ . , tj could be one trading day or one calendar day. For each i G {0, . . . , N) and each k G {1, . . . , K}, we suppose that we are given N(k, i) > 0 bonds of issuer k that traded on the date Dt. For each traded bond, we are given, besides the issuer and the trading date, the settlement, the maturity, the coupon rate, the annual coupon frequency (a divisor of 12) and the traded yield. For each (k, i), we suppose that the N(k, i) bonds have distinct maturities. Let these bonds be indexed by G {1, . . . , N(k, i)}. Let the maturity (in days) of bond a be τ^' ] and let its traded yield be y 'l There is no loss of generality in supposing that 0 < τjfc'^ < . . . < r^X' y We will use the symbol π to represent the traded bond data.
Definition
K{k, i, m) = l ≤ k ≤ K Λ 0 < i < N Λ l < m < β{k) A (3α)(l < α < N(k, i) Λ τ< 'f> G B )
"Some bond whose issuer is k and whose maturity fell in bucket m traded on date i. "
Note that K(k, i, m) depends both on π and on the maturity buckets
rate r k
ed
Figure imgf000065_0001
We will need the following two conversion functions :
FROMCONTINUOUS(r, F) ^ rχ{F=∞} + F(erX - \)χ{o<F<∞) TOCONTINUOUS(r, F) rχ{F=∞} + F(ln(l + r/F)χ{0<F<∞} for F G (0, +oo] and r G E.
If r is a continuously compounding rate, then FROMCONTINUOUS(r, F) is the corresponding rate of compounding frequency F. If r is a rate of compounding frequency F, then TOCONTINUOUS{r, F) is the corresponding continuously compounding rate.
Definition
For a curve C and a maturity r, let C f r be the restriction of C to the maturity points < r.
Calibration Functions
Given ft G {1, .. . , Λ"}, i G {0, .. . , N] and π, we can construct a curve
Figure imgf000065_0002
: for ft = 1 to K for i = 0 to N C(*.*)(?r) «- 0 for = 1 to JV(ft, i) Note that, when calculating r(y£fc,i) ^^ (π)), we use l(k B and PW. Once the curve construction has been completed, each curve ^k'^ {ιt), associated with issuer ft and trading date Di, has N(k,i) maturity points, and, for each a G {1, . .. , N(k, i)}, the yield of bond implied by CW* (it) \ τik'i} is the given yield yi . Thus we may say that the curves {C^ ( )),. .. are calibrated against the traded bond data π.
We can now interpolate the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates :
Figure imgf000066_0001
Suppose that X — (X(k,i,m)) ~,Kιk j m\ is n estimate of the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates and Y = (Y(k,i, ))κ(k,i,m) is an estimate of the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates. Then we can form an estimate R(X, Y) = (R{kιijTn) (X, Y)) ik . m) of all the rates Rt (p (m) by putting
•β(fc, i,m) ( x Y) = X(k,i,m)X{->K{k,i,tn)} + Y(k,i,m)X{K(k,i,m)}-
We now show how to construct calibrated curves given π and an estimate X of the "unknown" (standard maturity zero coupon) rates : for ft = 1 to K for i = 0 to N
Figure imgf000066_0002
We also have
Figure imgf000066_0003
We can define a vector of calibrated "known" rates :
C(X, it) ~ (FROMCONTINUOUS(XW (M% > , C (X, it)) , F^))κ{k,i>m) .
There can be some loss of information in passing from (C^k'^ {X, π))' (k , ) to R(X,C(X, ιt)).
Modelling Zero Coupon Rate Series as (G)BM
We now assume that each R^> (m) is specified as either a BM or a GBM. If we define χ(fe>(ro) = (Xf (fe>( ))i6R by putting (fc) ( M i ^ (m) if Rik) (m) is a BM
* \ ln(Λ[fc)(m)) if Λ *>( ) iβ a GB μ^ (m) be (fc,m), X^ m)
Figure imgf000067_0001
(k')( '
We assume that each R^ m) is "known" at some ti (or, equivalently, at some Di), that is,
(\/ke{l,...,K})(\fme{l,...,βW})(3i)K(k,i,m).
Figure imgf000067_0002
->K(k,a,m)
Figure imgf000067_0003
with t e time imension appearng vertca y.
Definitions df j R ] (m) - R ] (m) if R[k) (m) is a BM
Δ(Λ>ft,iι,i2,m) = ^ ,,-Wω/p{t)/ \ ln(R^ ( )/^ (m)) if R^ (m) is a GBM
AK(k,i,m) = K(k,i,m) A K(k,i-l,τn). We now put
£ = ( (R,k,iι,i2,m))V(kj i2,m) θ = (Δ(JR,ft,ϊ"-l,i,m))_lΔΛr( ιmv
Then the Brownian Motion assumption implies that
Figure imgf000067_0004
where
Figure imgf000067_0005
= h2 - iij , and cov(A(R,k,iι,i2,m),A(R,k',i'1,i'2,m')) =
Figure imgf000067_0006
Thus we can calculate E(ξ), E{θ), coυ(ξ,ξ), cov(θ,ξ), and coυ[θ,θ).
Now we can define x(Y) = (x(Y)ik,i1,i2,rn))v{k,i1,i2,m), s a function of some given Y = (ir(w,m))κ(fc,i,m)» by putting if P(fc)M is M if Λ(*)(m) is a GBM
Figure imgf000067_0007
Then we can calculate
E(θ\ξ = x(Y)) = E(θ) + cov(θ,ξ)coυ(ξ,ξ {x(Y) - E(ξ)) and cov(θ,θ I ξ = x(Y)) =cσυ(θ,θ) - cov(θ,ξ)cov(ξ,ξ)®cov(ξ,θ).
Figure imgf000068_0001
Let us denote by E(x \y = Y) the vector of "unknown" rates R..' (τrι) "backed out" from E(θ | ξ = x(Y)) given y = y, that is, filling using expected rate changes. Say
E(x\y = Y) = (E(R^(m) | y = y))^(fc,4,m).
We have still to solve for Y.
Estimating Expected Zero Coupon Rates
We put Yo = C(τt) and X0 = £?(» | y = Y0). For n > 1, we put Fn = C( „_1; π) and Xn = -5(a; | y = Yn). We continue calculating until \\Yn — Fn-ι|| = 0 (or, in practice, until \\Yn — Yn-ι\\ = 0 is sufficiently small). We then put
X ^ χn(= χn_x) and Y = Yn(= yn_ι), and get X = E(x | y = r) and y = C( , 7r). We can take P( , V) to be a reasonable proxy for the expectation of ti ^n))(k,i,m) conditional on the traded bond data it. Note that correlation effects across maturities, issuers and trading dates have been progressively incorporated into X and Y in the course of the iteration.
Estimating the Modes of the Zero Coupon Rates
We put Y0 C{τt) and X0 = E(x\y- Y0). For n > 1, we put Yn = C(X„_ι,π) and n = E(x \y = Yn). We continue calculating until \\Yn - yn-ι||oo = 0. We then put X = Xn{= Xn_x) and Y =f Yn(= Yn-χ), and get X = E(x\y = Y) and y = C(X, it). We can take P( , Y) to be a reasonable proxy for the modes of R[" (m), for (ft, ι, ), conditional on the traded bond data it.
Note that, for both these ways of estimating the zero coupon rates, we can use the curves (C^k'^ (X, t))(k,i) to price non-traded bonds of issuers 1, ... , K at the trading dates Do,--., D^.
Simulating the Zero Coupon Rates
Let X and Y be calculated either as conditional modes or as conditional expectations. Then we have either X — E(x | y — Y) and Y = C(X, it), or
X = E(x I y = Y) and Y = C{X, it). We can use E(θ\ξ = x{Y)) and coυ(θ, θ I £ = x(Y)) to calculate a random drawing θ of the normal random vector θ. From θ and y, we can derive X = ( (fc,i,m))-.ir(fc,i,m) by filling with simulated values. We can then recalibrate the "known" rates by putting Ϋ = C(X,ιt), and take R(X, Ϋ) to be an approximate random drawing of (R^ (™ )(k,i,m) conditional on the traded bond data it. We can use the simulated curves ((j(*>»)( ,7r))(fc?i to derive simulated prices of non-traded bonds of issuers 1.... , K at the trading dates D0, ■■■, DN-
Note
The assumption of consistency may not be satisfied if coυ(ξ,ξ) is singular.
Put T {{k,m) I (3»i)(3*2)V(Mi,t2,m)} and R' = (P(feV))(&,m)er- I the unconditional covariance matrix of R' per unit interval of time is non-singular, then cov(ξ, ξ) is also non-singular and the assumption of consistency is satisfied.
Modelling Spreads over a Base Issuer
We assume that the issuer indexed by ft = 1, the base issuer, is at all times of a higher credit quality than the other issuers. We assume that the number of maturity buckets is the same for each issuer, so that β^ — β(k ' for all ft, ft' G {1, ... , K}. The standard maturities would typically be chosen to be the same for each issuer, that is, ώ = Mm ' for all m G {1, ...,β(k)} and all k,k' £{1,...,K}.
For each ft G {1, ... , K} and each m G {1, ... , β^ }, we define the zero coupon rate spread series, S^(m) — Sf (m))tett, over the base issuer by putting
Slk)(m) R[k)(m) - P1}(m)X{fe> 1}.
K
We assume that (S^(m))m==lt ...w)k__1 κ is Geometric
Figure imgf000069_0001
Brownian Motion, thus ensuring that the spreads are pos ve. o. we define
-χW(m) (ln(S )(m)))t , we are assuming that ({X^ m))m=X_:βW) k=l,...,K
K is a / β^ -dimensional Brownian Motion. We suppose that the parameters of
Figure imgf000069_0002
this Brownian Motion are given. Let μ(k> (rή) be the mean of (the changes in) χ(k m) per unit interval of time, for each (ft, m), and let cov((m), ( .)) be the (m) and X(k ) (m') per unit interval
Figure imgf000069_0003
We already have
K(k,i,m) = l<k<K A 0<i<N A 1 < m < β(k)
A (3o)(l < < N(k,i) A rj*'** G B ). df
Let us define K*(k,i,m) — K(k,i,m) A (ft > 1 = - K(l,i,m)), "The spread Sfp{m) is 'known'."
We will say that
Figure imgf000069_0004
is "known" if K*(k, i, m) and "unknown" if ->K*(k, i, m).
We assume that each S^(m) is "known" at some t, that is,
(Vft G {1, ...,K})(Vm G {1, ...,βW})(Bi)K*(k,i,m).
For = (X(k,i,m))-,κ(k,i,m) and = (y"(fc,i,m))f(*,i,m), we can define S(X, Y) = (5( ,m) (X, y)) (fcim) by putting
S(k,i,m)(X,Y) = R(k,i,m) (X, Y) ~ R(l,i,m)(XχY)X{k> !}■ We then have
R(X,Y) = (S(k,i,m)(XχY) + S{1>i,mχl(X,Y)χ{k> 1}) (k,i,m)
Let us define ψk{a) = X{ = 1} + kX{a= 2}, or G {1, 2} and ke {1,...,K}. Then, for ft > 1 and given X and Y, we have
Σ S{ψk{o),i,m){XχY) = R(k,i, )(XχY)-
«=1
](m) for all (k,i,m) such that ft > 1. ,m) A ->K(l,i,m), where H stands for
Figure imgf000070_0001
Figure imgf000070_0002
For y = (y(fc,i,m))κ( .'n)) we define (Y) = ( (feιi,m) - ir(1,i,m)X{fc> i})K kAm) , the "known" spreads implied by the "known" rates.
Proposition
For W = (W(jfe,iim))(fc,iiro) and Y - (Y{k,i,m))κ(k,i,m)χ we have
(3X)(W = S(X,Y))
2
\ W*,i,m) = ψ(Y)(k,i,m)) Λ /^ (∑W(φfc(α))Am) = Y(k,i,m))- K*(k,i,m) H(k,i,m) a=l
Proof - S(X,Y). + 5(x,i,m)( ,K)X{fe> 1}
Figure imgf000070_0003
= -X"(*,t, )X{-.K'(fc,t,m)} + Y[k,i,m)X{K{k,i,m)}-
Suppose K"{k,i,m). case ft = 1
Then W{k ) = Y(k,i,m) - Ψ(Y)(k,i,m)- case ft > 1
Then K(k,i,m), K(l,i,m) and W( >ro) + W( >m) = F( ,m).
But ^(l.j.m) = Y(ι,i,m), because K(l,i,m), so that
W(k,i,m) = Y(k,i,m) ~Y(l,i,m) = Ψ(Y)(k,i,m)-
Thus we have shown /X (Wfj,*,™) = Ψ(Y)(k,i,m))-
K*{k,i,m)
Now suppose H(k,i,m). Then ft > 1, K(k,i,m) and -ιAT(l,ft, m), and we have ΣW(Vk(.«)),i,m) = W(k,i,m) + W( ,m) = W(fc,i,m) + W(l,i,m)X{ft> 1} = Y(k,i,m)-
<x=l
2
Thus we have shown ^ (∑W(¥>fc(α)),i,m) = Y(k,i,m))- (k,i,m) α=l
Now suppose
2 (W(ft,i,m) = φ(Y){k^m)) A /V ( W(Vfc))Λm) = Y(k,i,m))- K*(k,i,m) H(k,i,m) α=l
Put X = (W(jfc,,-,m) + W( , )X{A> ι})-.K(fc,i,m)-
We show that W = S(X,Y). case ft = 1 d if(ft, i, ) Then
Sik>i,m)(X,Y) = R{k,iM(X,Y) (k = l)
— Y(k,i,m) (ft = 1 and K(k, i, πi))
= Φ(Y)(k,i,m) (k = 1 and K(k,i,m))
= W(*,i." (K*(k,i,m)). case ft = 1 αrc ~ιK(k, i, m) Then
^.iιm)(x,F) = p( ,m)(x,y) (ft = i)
= ■^'(ft.i.m) (fc = 1 and-.ϋ'(ft, , ))
= W(k,i,m) (ft = 1 and definition of X). case ft > 1 and K(k,i,m) and^K(l,i,m)
Then K*{k,i,m) and < ,,,„*) (X, ) = (fcιijm) - Y^ti,m) = Φ{Y)(k,i,m) = W{k tTn). case ft > 1 and K(k,i,m) and K(l,i,m)
Then H(k,i,m) and 5{fc)i)m) (X, y) = F(J ιm) -X( >m) = Y(k,i,m) ~ W( ,m).
But H(k,i,m) implies that W(1ATO) + W(fc,»,m) = (fc,»,m)) so that
S(k,i,m) (X, Y) = W(l,i,m) +W(k,i,m) ~ W(l,i,n») = W(Λ,«,m)- case ft > 1 and -<K(k,i,m) and K(l,i,m) Then
S{k,i,m) { x Y) — X(k,i,m) - Y(l,i,m)
Figure imgf000071_0001
= W{k,i,m) + W(l,i,m) - W(l,t,m) (■K'*(&> *, m))
Figure imgf000071_0002
case ft > 1 and ->K(k,i,m) and -χK(l,i,m) Then
S(k,i,m) ( x Y) — X(k,i,m) ~ X(l,i,m)
= W(fc,t,ro) + W(l,i,m) - W(iii)7n)
= W( ,n»)-
Thus we have S(k,i,m)(X,Y) = W(fc,«>"») m a cases, so that 5(X, Y) — W.
Note that the proof shows that if (3X)(W = ι?(X, Y)), then such an " is unique (because it must be equal to (W( ,m) + Wr(1,i,m)X{fe> ι})-Λr(fc,i,m))- Now suppose that H(k, i, m). Then, for = 1, 2, we can choose ,m) G {0, 1, .. • , JV} such that \tg,,,Mi - £;| = inf{\ - \ \ K*(φk(a),i',m)} and K*(φk{ ), k,i'm) , m). The existence of each 'm) follows from the assumption that each S^(m) is "known" at some date. Note that L^'1'"^ is the time index of the "known" spread of the form S^ (m) that is closest in time to Slfk{a))(m). There may be two choices for ι( Λ'm) . Note also that t£Λ'm} ≠ i because H(k,i,m) implies that ->K*(φk(a),i, m), for a = 1,2. We can also define
„(k,i,m) ϊ_£ ... .. - xχx^< i} ~ ^{ fc"''m)> iV for a = 1,2. We will often omit the superscript ()(*.*.«") from t£W,TO) and sLfc'i,m).
Definitions
Figure imgf000072_0001
Δ*(W,Λ,t1>t3>m) ^ In ffl g) , for W = (Wr(*,i,m))(*1i.m)- Then, given M[k,i,m), the Geometric Brownian Motion assumption implies that
St (r(α) ) _ 5£λ'(£ϊ))(7n)exp(s„ Δ* (S,ψk(a), in(i,ιa),max(i,ιa),m)), for α = 1, 2. We will sometimes use the alternative notation S(k,i,m) f°r ^ (tn).
As before, we define y = (ϊ*, (m))jRr(A,i, )-
We also define y* = (£4; (m))-KT* ,m)- Note that y = Y implies that y* = Φ(Y).
Let us also define
Figure imgf000072_0002
12-1 i2>h A K*(k,iι,m) A K*(k,i2,m) A ff ~>K*(k,a,m)
and AK*{k,i,m) = K*(k,i,m) A K*(k,i-l,m).
We put θ = ( *(S,k,i - l,i,m))ΔK*(fc,i,rov
Suppose that we are given Y = (Y(k,i,m))κ(k,i,m)χ n estimate of the "known" zero coupon rates. First suppose (\/(k,i,m))-Η(k,i,m). We then put ξ = (A*(S,k,ii,i2,m))v.(k,i1,i2lm)> x(Y) d In
,Ψ{Y)(k,iι,m)J) V*(fc,»ι,»2,τn)
Then I „ ] is normal. Now
E(A*(S,k,i1,i2,m)) = Atil μW(m), where At{ltii = 2 — t^, and cov{A*(S,k, ,i2,m),A*(S,k',i'x,i2',m')) =
Thus we can calculate Eξ), E(θ), cov(ξ,ξ), coυ(θ,ξ) (and coυ(θ,θ)), and therefore also
E(θ\ζ = x(Y)) = E{θ) + cov(θ, ξ)cov(ξ, 0®(x( ) - E(ξ)).
Given E(θ | ξ = x(Y)) and assuming y* = φ(Y), we can fill the spreads, using expected spread changes, to get, say,
E(S\ξ = x(Y)) = (E(S^(m) I ξ = x(Y))){k,i,m).
But then we have x(Y)) = φ(Y)(ki,m)) and
Figure imgf000073_0001
{V{k,i,m)XH{k,i,m), so that E(S | ξ = x(Y)) = S(X{Y),Y), where
X(Y) = (E(S{ }(m) j ξ = x(y)) +
Figure imgf000073_0002
| ξ = x(y))χ{fe> 1})-,w,ro).
Figure imgf000073_0003
Now suppose that (3(k,i,m))H(k,i,m).
For each (k,i,m) satisfying H(k,i,m), let us define
for =
Figure imgf000073_0004
for = (^α)α=l,2 G I2.
Then, given H(k,i,m) and 2 = y (and omitting the superscripts ()(*>l>m)), we have
Figure imgf000073_0005
= ^ 41 (m) exp(sα Δ* (S, ψk {a), min(i, ua), max(i, ιa), m)) α=l
= Fγ((sa Δ* (S,ipk(a),min(i,La),max(i,ia),m))a=Xt2).
Figure imgf000073_0006
we have, again omitting the superscripts Q(fe>»>m) 5 ff0)){Z) = Fy(zM) + Fy(zM)(Z-ZW)
= ∑ aa(Y)e^ + ∑g (Z^)(Za - 2 >) α-=l α=l
2 2
= J αα( )e^01 + ∑ α(y)e^0) ( β - 0)) a=l «=1
Figure imgf000074_0001
If r
whe
Figure imgf000074_0002
Given H(k,i,m), we have
Figure imgf000074_0003
£(α + 6τZ) = α + 6τ (Z)
= α + 0 ' s2i(fc)(ϊ")Δtmm(i,t2),mαa:(i,<.2) cov(a + bTZ, a' + b,TZ') = bτcoυ(Z, Z')b', and cov(Za,Zc'x,) =
/ / \\ / r x\ \ max(i,ι.a) max(i',ι ,)
X l=m (i,t«)+ll'=mm(»',ι',)+l so that cov{a + bTZ,a' + blTZ') =
Figure imgf000075_0001
mω(t,ιβ) max(ϊ ,t,'a,)
l=min Σ(i,ι,a)+l l'=min Σ(i' ,ι' ,)+l *.«'Δ*«-
We also have coυ(a + 6r ,Δ*(5,ft",z , ',m")) =
Figure imgf000075_0002
Thus we can calculate
Figure imgf000075_0003
and therefore also
Figure imgf000075_0004
Given E(θ ) ^0)(^) = x(Y)) and assuming y* = φ(Y), we can "back out" the spreads (filling using expected spread changes) to get, say,
E(S I ξ^(Y) = x(Y)) = CE(4fc)(m) I ξW{Y) = χrY)))(k,i,m).
We then put S0 = ^(5 | ξ<°)(y) = z(F)). Note that there does not necessarily exist some X such that So = S(X, Y). case n > 0
We let <")(y) = (&n)(Y))r be indexed by all (k,iι,i3,m) such that
V*(k,iι,i ,m) and by all (k,i,m) such that H(k,i,πι).
If r corresponds to F*(ft, ii,&2,m), we define r (Y) = A*(S,k,iι,i2,m). If r corresponds to H(k,i,m), we define
Figure imgf000075_0005
where Zn - ((sa A* (Sn-χ,ψk(a), in(i,ιa),max(ϊ,ιa),m))a=1fi)-
( £( )(Y) \ Then I ' l is normal. Using the formulae given for the case n — 0, we can calculate E(ξ^(Y)), E(θ), cov(ξ(-n>'(Y),ξ^(Y)) and coυ(θ,ξ^(Y)), and therefore also
E(θ\ξ^(Y) = x(Y)) =
E(θ) +coυ(θ,ξ^(Y))coυ(ξ{nHY),ξ{n)(Y))@(x(Y) ~ E(^n)(Y)))-
Figure imgf000076_0001
Hk,i,m), we have
Figure imgf000076_0002
X { )exP(ln te
2 αα(y)exp(sα Δ* (Snk(a) ,min(i, ta) ,max(i, (■<*), m)) α=l
= Fy(Zn+1) and
Figure imgf000076_0003
= fv ((s« * (Sn,ψk(a),min(i,ιa),max(i,ia),m))a~ιt2)
by the construction of Sn .
We continue calculating until || Sn — Sn-ι || = 0.
Then we put S(Y) =f Sn. Say S(Y) = (S(k,i>m)(Y))(k^m).
Then clearly /X (S(k m)(Y) = φ(Y)(k,i,m)), and, given H(k,i,m), we have
K'(k,i,m) 2 2 (v>fc(c<),i,m)0 = OSτι)tø*(α),i,nι)00 α=l α=l
= y(^n+ι)
- Jy (Zn+i)
=
Figure imgf000076_0004
{Zn+1 = Zn because Sn = S„-ι)
— (k,i,m)x
2
SO that /^ (∑S(,φk(a),i,m)(Y) = Y(k,i,m))- H(k,i,m) a=l
Therefore S(Y) = S(X(Y),Y), where
X(y) = (S{kΛM(Y) + S( <m)(Y)χ{k> ι})^κ{k>iιm) ■ wePutξ(y) (τι)( ).
Thus, in all cases, we have S{X{Y),Y) = S | ξ{Y) = a;(Y)). Now let E(S \y = Y) = {E{S^k)(m))(k>itm) be "backed out" from
E(θ\y * = φ(Y) A / (∑s(Vfc(o)ιi,m)(y) = y{ ,m))) ff(ft,i,m) =l assuming y* = ψ(Y) (filling using expected spread changes). Then E(S | y = Y) is well-defined, even though we may not know how to evaluate it : we do not necessarily know how to evaluate
2
E(θ I y* = φ(Y) A ΛV (∑5(Vh(β)Am)(y) = y(fc,i,TO))). We can notionally "back out" E(R I V = Y) = (E(Rt {k)(m) | p = y))(jk , ro) from £(5 I y = y) by defining
£( * ) I 12 = y)χ{*> 1}. So we have S(X(
Figure imgf000077_0001
(Y) is equivalent to
/ft (A^S,k,i1,i2,m)=ln(Φ^( k'i^
H(k,i,m)
((sa Δ* (S,ψk( ),min(i, ca),max(i, ta),m))a:=h2) = y^,,-,™)), and y* — φ(Y) implies that
Figure imgf000077_0002
and, for each H{k,i,m), /«'-Δ'(5(Ar(y),r),^(α),min(i,»α),mαx(i,),B,))β=1.a) Jg ^ affine approximation of at
(sα Δ* (SX(Y),Y),φk{a),min{i,t,a),max{i,ι.a),m))a==lι2, and
2 jFHfsα Δ* (S,φk( ),min(i,ιa),max(i, έ ( fc(α))(m).
Figure imgf000077_0003
Thus S(X(Y),Y) « £( I y = y) and #(X(y), K) w £(Λ | » = F).
Note that if (\/(k,i,m))-χH(k,i,m), we have S(X(y),y) = £(S | y = Y) and
Λ( (3 , Y) = E(R \y = Y)- We now solve for Y. We put y0 = C(τr) and
Xo = X(Yo)- For n > 1, we put Yn — C(Xn-\,τt) and X„ = X(yn). We continue calculating until \\Yn — yn-ι||oo = 0. We then put Y = Y„(= Yn-ι) and
X I χn(= X(Y) = χn_x), and get Y = C(X, π) and
X m (E(R . (m) I y = Y))-,κ(k,i,m)- Note that, for each H{k,i,m), we have used an affine approximation of ∑Siy' (m) by a normally distributed random α=l variable. We can take iϊ(X, ) to be a reasonable proxy for the modes of Rip (m), for (k,i,m), conditional on the traded bond data it. Note that, for (k,i,m) with ft > 1, we have R(k,i,m) (X, Y) > R(ι,i,m){X-> Y)- We can use the curves (£( ( j π))(jtji) to price non-traded bonds of issuers 1, ... , K at the trading dates DQ,...,DN.
Note
When calculating X{Yn) for n > 0, we can use, for each H(k,i,τn), the last calculated iterate of Zm, depending on Yn~ι, in place of Z0, depending on Yn, as the initial estimate of the vector at which to take the affine approximation of Fγn . This should accelerate convergence.
Simulating the Zero Coupon Rates
Given X and Y, calculated as above, we can use E(θ | ξ(Y) = x(Y)) and coυ(θ,θ I ξ(Y) = x(Y)) = cσv(θ,θ) - cσυ(θ,ξ(Y))cσυ(ξ(Y),ς(Y))®cov(ξ(Y),θ) to calculate an approximate random drawing θ of the normal random vector θ. From θ and assuming y* = φ(Y), we can "back out" S0 - ((So)(k,i,m))(k,i,m) by filling with simulated spread values. Note that there may not exist some X' such that
So = S(X',Y). We put X = ((S0)(k,i,m) + (So)(ι,i,m)X{k> ι})-,κ(k,i,m) and recalibrate the "known" rates by putting Y — C(X, it). Then we can take R(X, Y) to be an approximate random drawing of (R) (m))(k^iΛn conditional on the traded bond data it, and we can use the simulated curves (C^k,i^ (X ,τt))ιk^ to derive simulated prices of bonds of issuers 1, ... , K at the trading dates Do,- ..,IΛr-
Note
The assumption of consistency may not be satisfied if coυ(ξ(Y),ξ(Y)) is singular for some Y. Put T = {(k,m) | (3zι)(3i2)y*(ft,i1;ϊ"2,m) Λ (3i)H{k,i,m)} and
S' = ( (ft)(m))(fc.m er-. If the unconditional covariance matrix of S' per unit interval of time is non-singular, then cov(ξ(Y),ξ(Y)) is also non-singular for any Y, and the assumption of consistency is necessarily satisfied.
Modelling Successive Spreads
We assume that the issuers indexed by ft = 1, .... it are at all times in strictly decreasing order of credit quality. In fact, we can here interpret issuers to mean issuer classes, say those defined by some ratings agency, rather than individual issuers. As before, we assume that the number of maturity buckets is the same for each issuer, and the standard maturities would typically be chosen to be the same for each issuer.
For each ft G {1, ... ,K} and each G {1, ... ,β^}, we define the successive spread series, S^ (TO) = (S* {m))teR, by putting
4 ) = Rik)(m) - ik-1](m)χ{k> 1}.
K
((χ(fc)(m))m=lι ...,βm)k_1 κ is a ^ig(fc)-dimensional Brownian Motion. We
Figure imgf000078_0001
We already have
K{k,i,m) = l<k<K A 0<i<N A l<m< β(k) A (3α)(l < a < N(k,i) A T^ G B%>).
Let us define K*(k,i,m) = K(k,i,m) A (ft > 1 =- K(k — l,i,m)), "The successive spread ^ '(m) is 'known'."
We will say that S. (m) is "known" if K* (ft, i,m) and "unknown" if ->K* (ft, i,m).
We assume that each S^(m) is "known" at some ti, that is,
(\fke{l,...,K})(Mm {l,...,β^})(3i)K*(k,i,m). m))κ(k,i,m), we define S(X,Y)
Figure imgf000079_0001
- R(k-ι,i, )(X,Y)X{k> 1}.
We then have
R(x,γ)= ∑s(α>i,m)(x,y)
(k,i,τn)
We also define
Figure imgf000079_0002
(fcx = 0 V K(k i,m)) A k2 > ft'i + 1 fc2-ι Λϋ(ft2,i,m) Λ y^(y -<ϋ( ,i,m). α=feι+l
Then if(ftι,ft2',m) =J> ft2 > 1. For y = (K(j,i,m))κ(fc,f,m). we define φ(Y) = (Y(k,i,m) ~ Y(k-l,i,m)X{k> l})jc*(k,i,m) ' the "known" successive spreads implied by the "known" rates.
Proposition
For W = (W(k,i,m))(.k,i,m) nd Y = (Y(k,i,m))κ{k,i,m), we have
(3X)(W = S(X,Y))
Λ ~ Y(kχ,i,m)X{kχ> 0}) ■
Figure imgf000079_0003
Proof
(=»)
Suppose that X = ( ^^m))-^*,*,™) satisfies W = S(X,Y). Then, for all (ft, i, m), we have
∑ W(a,i,m) = ∑ <S ,m)(X,y) α=l =l
Figure imgf000079_0004
= X(k,i,m)X{->K(k,i,m)} + Y(k,i,m)X{K(k,i,m)}-
Suppose K* (ft, i, m) . case ft = 1
Then W(fc,i,ro) = Y(fc,i,m) = O (fc,i,m)- case ft > 1
Then K(k, i, m) and if (ft - 1, i, m), so that k k—X
W(k,i,m) = ∑ W( Am) ~ ∑ W ,m) α=l <ϊ=l
= -R(fc,i,m)(X,y) - R(k-l,i, )(X,Y)
— Y(k,i,m)(X,Y) - Y(k-l,i, )(X,Y)
Figure imgf000079_0005
Thus we have shown ^ (W{k,i, ) = Φ(Y)(k,i,m))-
K"{k,i,m)
Now suppose H(kχ,k2,i,m). case fti = 0
Figure imgf000080_0001
fca k2
∑ W(C£)iιm) = W(a)i,m) =kl+l a=l
Figure imgf000080_0002
= Y(k2,i,m)(X,Y) -Y{ki,i,m){X,Y)X{k1>0}- case kx > 0
Then K(k2,i,m) and K{k\,i,m), so that
W(<-,i,m)
Figure imgf000080_0003
= •R(fc2,i>n»)(X,r) - R(k!,i,m)(X,Y)
= Y(k2,i,m)(X,Y) -Y(kι,i,m)(X,Y)
= Y(k2,i,τn)(X,Y) -Y(kι,i,m)(X,Y)X{kι>0}- k2
Thus we have shown ff ( W(c ,m) = Y(k2,i,m) ~ Y(k1,i, )X{k1>o})- {k\,k2,i,m) a=kχ+l
Now suppose
- (fclΛm)χ{Al>0}).
Figure imgf000080_0004
ff(feι,fc2,i, ) α=fcι+l
We put X = £W(a,w (i,w and show that W = S(X,Y). ft=l k
We first show that K(k,i,m) = ^(fc.i.m) = ∑W(0,ιj>TO), which we prove by
«=ι induction. Let us define fl-„ (Vft)(Vi)(Vm)((UT(fc,i, ) Λ |{ft' | 1 < ft' < ft Λ K(k',i,m)}\ = n) k
Figure imgf000080_0005
It is enough to show Jn for all n > 0. We first show H- Suppose K(k, i, m) and I {ft' I 1 < ft' < ft Λ K(k',i,m)}.\ = 0. Then H(0,k,i,m), so that k k
∑W(«,i,ro) = ∑ W(α,i,m) = Y(k,i,m)χ by our assumption. Now suppose α=l α=0+l
Uo, - - • , it" n-ι for some n > 0. We show Hn. Suppose K(k, i, m) and
I {ft' I 1 < ft' < ft Λ K(k',i,m)}\ =n. Then there is a ft* G {l,...,ft- 1} such that H(k*, k, i, m). Thus we have K(k*, i, m) and
|{fc' I 1 < ft' < ft* Λ K{k',i, m)}\ < n, whence, by the induction hypothesis, fc*
Y(k*,i,m) = ∑W(α,»,m)- But H(k*, k,i, m) implies that α=l k
Figure imgf000081_0001
Thus we have Hn for all n > 0, and R{X, Y) = (^ j,ra))(i,i,m), so that α=l S(X, y) = (R k,i,m) { x Y) ~ R{k-l,i,m) { x Y)X{k> l})(k,i,m)
Figure imgf000081_0002
=W(θi,i,m) ~ W(ec,i,m)X{k> l})(k,i,m) α=l α=l
— " (k,i,m))(k,i,τn)
= w.
Note that the proof shows that if (3X)(W = S(X, Y)), then such an X is unique (and is equal to (∑W(α,»,m))-./r(fc,t,m))- α=l
Figure imgf000081_0003
Definitions
Figure imgf000081_0004
A*(W, k, ix, i2,m) £ In ( g }) , for W = (W(fcAr,))(WjTB).
Then, given iϊ(ftι, ft2, i, m), the Geometric Brownian Motion assumption implies that - (w = 4 (m) eXP(sα Δ* (S, α, min(i, tα), mαx(i, iα), m)), for α = fti + 1, . . . , ft2. We will sometimes use the alternative notation S(fc,,)m) for
4V)-
As before, we define y = (Rlk) (m))K(k,i,m)-
We .also define y* = (S(. (ιn))κ*(k,i,m)- Note that y = Y implies that y* = φ(Y). Let us also define
V*(k,iι,i2,m) =
J3-1 i2>iχ A K*(k,iι,m) A K*(k,i2,m) A /ft ->K*(k,a,m) α=iι+l and AK*(k,i,m) = K*(k,i,m) A K*(k,i = l,m). We put θ = (A*(S,k,i- l,i,TO))ΔΛ-.*(jb,i, )-
Suppose that we are given Y = (Y(k,i,m))κ(k,i,m)x an estimate of the "known" zero coupon rates. First suppose (V(fcι,ft2,i,m))-'.Hr(ftι,ft2,i,m). We then put ξ = (A*{S,k,iι,i2,m))v*(k,il,i2, ),
*() M p* ))
Then f jj J is normal. Now
E{A*(S,k,i i2,m)) = ΔtilAμ<*>(m), where t^,^ — ti2τ, and ccw(Δ*(S,fc,iι,22,ra),Δ*(S,fc',ii,i2,m')) =
Figure imgf000082_0001
Thus we can calculate £(£), ■#(#), ccw( , £), coυ(θ,ξ) (and coυ(θ,θ)), and therefore also
E(0 K = sO ) = £(0) + cov(θ,ξ)cov(ζ,ξ)®(x(Y) - E(ξ)).
Given E(θ \ ξ = xiY)) and assuming y* = φ(Y), we can fill the spreads, using expected spread changes, to get, say,
E.(S\ξ = x(Y)) = ?(m) I ξ = χ(Y)))[k,i,m)- But then we have /ft (E(S[k) {m)\ξ = x(Y)) = φ(Y){k^m)) and
K*(k,i,m)
(\f(k1,k2,i,m))~χH{k1,k2,i,m), so that E(S | ξ = x(Y)) = S(X(Y),Y), where
X(Y) = (∑ E(Si (m) I ξ = X(Y))XK(k,i>m). α=l
We put f (V) ξ.
Now suppose that (3(fcι,ft2,i,m))iϊ(fcι,ft2,i,m).
For each (fel5 fc2,i,τn) satisfying H(kι,k2,i,m), let us define
Figure imgf000082_0002
for = fti + 1, ... , ft2, and
Figure imgf000083_0001
for Z = (Za)a=kl+ ...,k2 G K*»-*'.
Then, given H(kx,k2,i,m) and y = Y, we have
Σ 4QV) =&ι+l
= ∑ S^ ( ) exp(sα Δ* (S, α, m»n(j, tα), max(i, ta), m)) a=k\+l
= Fγ((sa A* (S,a,min(i,ιa),max(i,ιa),m))a-k1t...,k!i).
But Fγ((sa A* (S, ,min{i,ia),max{i,ta),m))a=k1+ι,...,k2) is not, in general, normal because Fy is non-linear. Let (_/ * • >i'm))(2(0)) ) or just f m be the affine approximation of Fy at Z<°> = (z })a=kl+1<...ιk2 G E*2-*1. Then, given Z = (Za)a=kl+lι... G fc2-feS we have fγ zm z) = Fγ(zW) + Fγ(ZW)(Z-ZW)
= ∑ β β(y)ea?)+ ∑ g§β(s<°>)(z« -*?>) =feι+l a=kχ+l
= α(r)e^(2α-^)
Figure imgf000083_0002
Figure imgf000083_0003
So, for any Z^ G IR2"*1 (and given H(kx,k2,i,m)), /z(0))(Z) is of the form G K*2-*1, assuming that Z is represented
Figure imgf000083_0004
as a column vector.
Figure imgf000083_0005
H(kι,k2,i,m), we put r(y) = Y(k2,i,m) - Y(k1,i,m)X{k1> o}-
We now calculate XiY) iteratively. case n = 0
We let f(°)(y) = (^°}(Y))r be indexed by all ( ι,»2,m) such that
V*(k,iι,i2,m) and by all (fcι,ft2, i,m) such that H(kι,k2,i,m).
If r corresponds to V*(fc,iι,Ϊ2,m), we put HY) = A*{S,k,i1,i2,m).
Ur corresponds to iϊ(ftι,ft2,ι,m), we put °Hγ) = Zθ)((sα Δ* (S, ,πιin(i, ιa),max(i, ιa),m))a=kl+ ... ), where
Figure imgf000084_0001
A straightforward calculation shows that iϊ(ftι,ft2,i,m) implies that
Fγ(Zo) = Y(ki,i, ) - Y(k1,i,m)X{k1> 0}- °)(y) λ
Then I j is normal.
We have already shown how to calculate E{A*(S, k,iι,i2,m)) and coυ(Δ*(S,fc,iι,i2,πι),Δ*(S,ft',i/ 1,i2,m)). Suppose Z = (sa Δ* (S,a,τnin(i,ιa),max(i,La),m))a=kl+ι,.„>k2, corresponding to H( ,k2,i,m), and Z' = (sa' Δ* (S, tmin(i t'a),max(i ι.' ,m))a^k, 1+ι,...,k2', corresponding to H(k'l,k2',i',m'), where s'a — sά1 '*2'1 '™ and ι'a — ta ' 2'1
Figure imgf000084_0002
Then, for ,α'el and b = ,&' = fe2 fcl Wg naye
V
Figure imgf000084_0003
K.,_
E(a±bTZ) = a- bTE(Z)
Figure imgf000084_0004
cov(a + bTZ, a' + b'TZ') = bτcσυ{Z,
Figure imgf000084_0005
and
Figure imgf000084_0006
for = fti + 1, ... , ft2 and a' = k[ + 1, ... , ft2, so that coυ(α + 6τZ,α' + 6'r ') =
Figure imgf000084_0007
We also have coυ(α+6r^,Δ*(S,ft" *1 j '2> ")) =
Figure imgf000084_0008
Thus we can calculate
Figure imgf000085_0001
and therefore also'
Figure imgf000085_0002
Given E(θ j ξ^(Y) = x(Y)) and assuming y* = φ(Y), we can "back out" the spreads (filling using expected spread changes) to get, say,
MS I ^( ) = xQO) = ( (S^(m) I ξW(Y) = x(Y)))ik,i,m
We then put S0 = E(S | f (°) (Y) = »(y)). Note that there does not necessarily exist some X such that So = S(X, Y). case n > 0
We let ζ<ri(Y) = (ξin)(Y))r be indexed by all (k,h,i2,m) such that
V*(k,iι,Ϊ2,m) and by all (fcι,ft2,i,m) such that ff(ftι,fc2,i,m).
If r corresponds to V*(k,iι,i2,m), we define ξr (Y) = A*(S,k,ii,i2,m). If r corresponds to ϋ(fcι, ft2,i,m.), we define
Figure imgf000085_0003
where Zn = ({sa A* (Sn-ι, ,min(i, ka),max(i, ιa),m))a=kι+ι k2)-
Then (ξ "# ) is normal. Using the formulae given for the case n = 0, we can calculate E(ξW(Y)), E(θ), coυ(ξ^(Y),ξ )'(Y)) and coυ(θ,ξ^(Y)), and therefore also
Figure imgf000085_0004
Given E(θ \ ξ(n)(Y) = κ(y)) and assuming y* — φ(Y), we can "back out" the spreads (filling using expected spread changes) to get, say, E(S | ξ^ ( ) = x{Y)) — Sn- There does not necessarily exist some X such that Sn = S(X,Y), but, given H(kι,k2,i, m), we have k2
/ , (Sn)(a,i,m)
Figure imgf000085_0005
= ∑ αα(y)e p(sQ. Δ* (Sn,a,min(i,ιa),max(i, iα)> )) α=:ftι+l = Fγ(Zn+ι) and o)( „+ι)
Figure imgf000085_0006
= •'•(fea..'m) "~ *(fcι,4,m)X{fcι> 0}> by the construction of Sn. We continue calculating until || Sn — S-ι ||= 0.
Then we put S(Y) £ Sn. Say 5(y) = (fl, ( lm)(r))(J ,m).
Then clearly /ft (S(k,i,m) (Y) = O ( ,m)), and, given H(kχ,k2,i, ), we have
Λr*(ft,i,m) 88 which the option traded. Each standard maturity implied volatility is then defined to be "known" at a given date if an option traded on the given date and the maturity of the option fell in the bucket associated with the standard maturity and the underlying asset of the option is that associated with the implied volatility. One needs to assume that each standard maturity implied volatility is "known" at at least one date. The algorithms described for modelling zero coupon rate curves carry over to the modelling of implied volatility curves except that there is no calibration step because the observed implied volatilities are given directly. One would, of course, need to interpolate the "known" standard maturity implied volatilities from the observed implied volatilities and from the observed implied volatilities together with estimates of the standard maturity implied volatilities that are not "known". One could model separate implied volatility curves for puts and for calls. One could add an extra dimension, say, for the degree to which an option was in- or out-of-the-money at the time of the trade. In this case one would specify, for each asset, a set of buckets and associated standard points for this second dimension. The unconditional implied volatility dynamics would then be based on ordered pairs, each consisting of a standard maturity and a standard point for the second dimension. One would also need to specify interpolation functions of two variables to allow interpolation from the resulting implied volatility surfaces.
4. The methodology can handle real, as opposed to nominal, zero coupon rates or spreads and capital-indexed bonds. One can also combine the modelling of real and nominal zero coupon rates or spreads.
5. One can use the given zero coupon rate or spread modelling for each of several economies and combine them using inter-economy correlations.
6. One can also combine the given zero coupon rate or spread modelling with the modelling of other rates such as foreign exchange rates or stock indices.
85 k% k
∑ s(( )Tn)(y) = ∑ (sn)(0,ιiιm)(y)
Figure imgf000087_0001
= Fγ(Zn+1)
= "+l)(i )
= fY Zn)(Zn+1) (Zn+1 = Zn because S„ = S„_ι)
so that
Figure imgf000087_0002
Therefore S(Y) = S(X(J ,F), where
Figure imgf000087_0003
Weputξ(Y) = ξ^(Y).
Thus, in all cases, we have S(X(Y), Y) = E(S \ ξ{Y) = x(Y)).
Now let
Figure imgf000087_0004
Y) = (J5(4fc)(m))(M,m) be "backed out" from
E{θ I y* = φ(Y) A /ft ( ∑ S(α>i,ro)(y) = (fe)i,m) - l(tllWX{tl>o}))
Figure imgf000087_0005
ΛΛ jr((scΔ*(S(X(V),y),oι1 'in(i,ια),mos(i)t<t), ))α=jb1+ι,...,fc2)
Λ /λ\ w
Figure imgf000087_0006
((sα Δ* (S,a,min(i, ta),max(i,
Figure imgf000087_0007
— Y(k2,i,m) ~ Y(k i,m)X{kι> 0}), and y* ~ φ(Y) implies that
/ft (Δ*( ,ftIiι,i2,m)
Figure imgf000087_0008
and, for each f(ftι,ft2,ϊ,m), y 1 2' is the affine approximation of .Fy at
(sa A* (S(X(Y),Y),a, in(i,ιa),πuιx(i,ιa),m))a=kι+ι,...,k3, and
Figure imgf000087_0009
Thus S(X(Y),Y) E(S\y = Y) and R(X{Y),Y) E{R\y = Y).
Note that if (V(k1,k2,i,m))-χH(k1,k2,i,m), we have S{X(Y),Y) =E{S\y = Y) and R(X(Y),Y) = E(R | » = y). We now solve for Y. We put y0 = C(π) and 86
X0 = X( 0). For n > 1, we put Yn = C(Xn-1,π) and Xn £ X(Yn). We continue calculating until \\Yn — yn-ι|| = 0. We then put Y = Yn(= Yn-ι) and X £ Xn(= X(Y) = X„_ι), and get Y = C(X, it) and
X « (E(Rl '(m) I y = Y))-,κ(k,i,m)- Note that, for each ϋ(ftι,ft2',ra), we have k2 used an affine approximation of ∑) (m) by a normally distributed random
Figure imgf000088_0001
variable. We can take R(X, Y) to be a reasonable proxy for the modes of Rg'trri), for (k,i,m), conditional on the traded bond data it. Note that, for (k,i,m) with ft > 1, we have R(k,i,m) ( x Y) > R(k-ι,i,m)(X,Y)- We can use the curves (CO ) ( , π))(feti) to price non-traded bonds of issuers 1, ... , K at the trading dates Dθ)- • • , .
Note
When calculating X(Yn) for n > 0, we can use, for each H(k\,k2,i,m), the last calculated iterate of Zm, depending on Yn-ι, in place of Z0, depending on Yn, as . the initial estimate of the vector at which to take the affine approximation of Fγn . This should accelerate convergence.
Figure imgf000088_0002
For (k,i,m), either there is a unique ft' such that
Figure imgf000088_0003
0<ft'<ft Λ K(k',i,m) A / ^K{a,i,m) a=k'+l or no such ft' exists. Let ψ(k, i, m) be the unique such ft' if it exists or 0 if it does not exist. Then we can define X = ( (X)tk im)) by putting X)(k,i,m) — Ytp{k,i,m),i,m)X{ψ{k,i,m)> 0} + / , (Sθ)(a,i,m)ι a=φ(k,i,m) +1 for -ιK(k,i,m). In the case where -χK(k,i,m) and K(k',i,m) for some ft' > ft, we can incorporate an error adjustment in the definition of (X)(k,i,m)- In this case, we can put fto = φ(k,i,m), fti £ inf{ft' I ft < ft' < f Λ K(k',i,m)}, hi
Y(kχ,i,m) ~ Y(_ko,i,m)X{k0> 0} 2_j (So)(a,i,m) df a=ko+l e(k0,kι,i,m) = fa — ko
Note that we have
Y(kχ,i,m) ~~ Y(ko,i,m)X{ko> 0}
Figure imgf000088_0004
87
We can then put df
(X)(k,i,τn) — Y(ko,i,m)X{ko> 0} + ∑ (S~o)(a,i,m) a=k0+l
+ (ft = k0)e(ko, kι, i, m).
We recalibrate the "known" rates by putting Ϋ £ C(X, τt). We can then take R(X, Ϋ) to be an approximate random drawing of (Rt (rn))(k,i,m) conditional on the traded bond data it. We can use the simulated curves (C^k'^(X, π))'rktix to derive simulated prices of bonds of issuers 1, . . . , K at the trading dates Do, - ■ ■ , DM-
Note
The assumption of consistency may not be satisfied if coυ(ξ(Y), ξ(Y)) is singular for some Y. Put
T £ {(k, m) \ (3i1)(3i2)V*(k, i1, i2, m)
A (3kι)(3k2){3i)(k1 + 1 < ft < ft2 Λ H(k1 , k2, i, m))} and S' = ( (fc)(m))(fc)m)er. If the unconditional covariance matrix of S' per unit interval of time is non^singular, then cov(ξ{Y), ξ(Y)) is also non-singular for any Y, and the assumption of consistency is necessarily satisfied.
Notes
1. Convergence is not guaranteed. For given inputs, a solution may not exist. If calibration yields a negative spread or a negative zero coupon rate that is modelled as a GBM, the algorithm will fail. If the assumed unconditional dynamics and the traded bond data together produce extreme conditions, the numerical methods employed may fail. In the case of modelling spreads, the numerical methods may also fail if the maturity bucketing is too coarse for the variability in the spreads implied by the traded bond data. If convergence is not sufficiently fast, it can occasionally help to take the next iterate to be, say, the average of the last two iterates. We have only ever found this to be useful for the inner (affine approximation) loop for modelling spreads.
2. One could use norms other than || || to test for convergence : any two norms on a finite-dimensional vector space are topologically equivalent.
3. The iterative technique of modelling zero coupon rate curves as a (G)BM can be adapted to handle implied volatility curves, futures curves, forward foreign exchange curves and other curves. By way of example, let us consider implied volatility curves. We can have an implied volatility curve for each underlying asset of the options with which one is concerned. The role of bond issuers is replaced by that of underlying assets. For each asset, one can specify, for options on the asset, a set of maturity buckets and associated standard maturities, as well as an interpolation function for the implied volatilities. The unconditional implied volatility dynamics can be specified as a GBM in several dimensions. Note that implied volatilities can never be negative. The traded implied volatility data is given by specifying observed implied volatilities. Each of these requires the specification of not only the implied volatility (expressed, say, as an annualised figure), but also the maturity of the associated option, the underlying asset and the date on THIS PAGE INTENTIONALLY LEFT BLANK
THIS PAGE INTENTIONALLY LEFT BLANK
THIS PAGE INTENTIONALLY LEFT BLANK
THIS PAGE INTENTIONALLY LEFT BLANK
THIS PAGE INTENTIONALLY LEFT BLANK
THIS PAGE INTENTIONALLY LEFT BLANK
THIS PAGE INTENTIONALLY LEFT BLANK
THIS PAGE INTENTIONALLY LEFT BLANK
Internalising the Calibration Process
The calibration functions that we defined earlier depended on the assumed zero coupon rate or spread dynamics only to the extent that the zero coupon rate or spread dynamics were incorporated into the current estimates of the "unknown" zero coupon rates. We now show how the calibration process can be made to depend directly on the assumed zero coupon rate or spread dynamics.
Suppose we have a traded bond whose issuer is (indexed by) k e {1,..., K] , whose yield is y and whose trading date is Dt and whose associated time is tt , for some i e {0,1,..., N} . Let (τ , , X J , ) ') j .<Ξ{ „l,...,a ,] be the cash-flow schedule of the bond, where, for j e {1,..., a} , Xj is the cash payment at maturity τ;- days (actual days from the trading datel ). Let τσ be the maturity (in days) of the settlement of the bond. df
Put n = βK ) (the number of maturity buckets for issuer k), and, for j e {l,...,n} ,
Figure imgf000098_0001
(the standard maturity zero coupon rate for issuer k and trading date Dt ). Let B be the base, that is, the notional number of days in the year, specified for issuer k. Let I{ι>rι) (mn,r^} De the specified interpolation function for issuer k, based on the points (n , r) , ... , (mn,rn) . Without loss of generality, we can suppose that /{(m rι) {m _r » returns, for a given maturity T (actual days from Di ), a continuously compounding zero coupon rate of base B .
We suppose that the function { ... α ((mι rι) (m r )} (τ) } is differentiable, as a
function of several variables, for the given maturities n , ..., mn and for any given maturity τ . This function is differentiable if the specified method of interpolation is, for example, linear, logarithmic linear, cubic spline or logarithmic cubic spline (on any basis), even though the function {(m]ιrι) (m,r)} *s not> m general, differentiable if the method of interpolation is linear or logarithmic linear. Then we can express the calibration requirement for the given traded bond by the equation
Figure imgf000099_0001
where Rw is the pricing function specified for bonds of issuer k. Note that the left hand side of the equation is a differentiable function of the zero coupon rate vector
and the right hand side is a calculated constant.
Figure imgf000099_0002
Thus we can express the calibration requirement for all the traded bonds (for all issuers and all trading dates) as a set of non-linear simultaneous equations (one equation for each traded bond) where the unknown variables are all random. This is true in the case of modelling spread series as a GBM as well in the case of modelling zero coupon rate series as a (G)BM because zero coupon rates are affine functions of spreads (and spreads are affine functions of zero coupon rates). In the case of modelling spread series as a GBM, the unknown variables can all be taken to be spreads.
Zero Coupon Rate Series Modelled as a (G)BM
First of all, we need to assume not only that each standard maturity zero coupon rate series is "known" at at least one of the specified times t0 , tx , ... , tN (or, equivalently, at at least one of the specified trading dates), but also that each of these zero coupon rate series is "unknown" at at least one of the specified times. We will see shortly the reason for this latter requirement. This new requirement can always be satisfied by adding, if need be, a new date (and associated time), at which all the zero coupon rates are necessarily "unknown", to the set of specified trading dates.
As before, we calculate the "knowns" and "unknowns" in turn until successive iterates for the "knowns" are equal (that is, until convergence is reached). There are no changes to the method of calculation of the first iterate of the "knowns". There are no changes to the method of calculation of any of the iterates of the "unknowns", given the "knowns", except that they must be based on expected zero coupon rate changes and not on expected zero coupon rates. Suppose that we are to calculate a second or later iterate of the "knowns", given the current estimate of the "unknowns" and the traded bond yields for all issuers and all trading dates. So, at this stage, the "knowns" have unknown values (are unknown) and the "unknowns" have known values (are known). As we showed above, we can express the calibration requirement, depending on the given traded yields, as a set of simultaneous equations whose unknown variables are the standard maturity zero coupon rates. Now some of these zero coupon rates are known (that is, are "unknown") and the others are unknown (that is, are "known"). Thus we get a set of simultaneous equations whose unknown variables are the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates.
Let us consider a "known" standard maturity zero coupon rate, say R, ) (m) for m e {1,..., β(k) } . Our assumption above means that the zero coupon rate series R(!c) (m) has at least one "unknown". Thus we can choose some i = z(i-''m) such that
Figure imgf000100_0001
χ{l<i] - χ{l>i} .
Then, if R(i)( ) is aBM, we have
R^ (m) = Rf w (m) + s{k m)A(R, k, rnin(z, i), rnax( , i), m) , and, if R w (m) is a GBM, we have R^(rn) = Rt^ m)exp(si i-m)A(R,k,πύn(i,ι), ax(i,i),m)) .
Note that the value of Rf w (m) is known because R k) (m) is "unknown" (-<K(k,ι,m)).
We can then replace each occurrence of an unknown ("known") standard maturity zero coupon rate in the simultaneous equations by an expression involving an unknown zero coupon rate change of the form
Δ(R,fc,min(i,t),max(z,t),m) . In fact, the left hand side of each equation becomes a differentiable function of such unknown zero coupon rate changes. Then, by a process of iterative refinement of affine approximations similar to that used before for the calculation of the "unknowns" in the case of spread modelling (successive spreads or spreads over a base issuer), we can derive the expected values of the unknown zero coupon rate changes. This makes use of the zero coupon rate dynamics. At each step of this iteration, the left hand side of each calibration equation, as a function of the unknown zero coupon rate changes figuring in the equation, is replaced by its affine approximation, depending on the applicable method of interpolation, and we add (to the conditioning) a linearised constraint for each calibration equation. The iteration (the affine approximation loop) requires recalculating, for each calibration equation, the vector of unknown zero coupon rate changes at which to take the affine approximation. We also have "vertical" constraints corresponding to "runs" (where a "run" corresponds to a zero coupon rate which is "unknown" (known) at two distinct trading dates and "known" (unknown) at each intermediate trading date). These "vertical" constraints do not change from one iteration to another of the affine approximation loop. Assuming convergence, we get the non-linear constraints satisfied exactly. The iterative process makes use of the assumed zero coupon rate dynamics as well as the estimates of the "unknown" zero coupon rate values and the traded yields, and handles all issuers and trading dates together. Given the expected values of the unknown zero coupon rate changes and the "unknown" zero coupon rate values, we can then "back out" the next iterate of the "known" zero coupon rate values. Once the outer loop converges (that is, when successive iterates for the
"knowns" are equal), the "knowns" and "unknowns" together determine the calibrated standard maturity curves based on expected zero coupon rate changes. With the new calibration process, there is no version based on expected zero coupon rates (as opposed to expected zero coupon rate changes). Note also that zero coupon curves are not constructed with maturities corresponding to the maturities of traded bonds (unless such maturities happen to be standard maturities) and that the definition of calibrated traded bonds no longer depends on restricting the maturities of the constructed curves.
To simulate calibrated zero coupon rate curves, we can simulate the "unknown" zero coupon rates, given the "knowns" provided by the curves based on expected zero coupon rate changes. Then we can calibrate the "knowns" as shown above, but using the simulated "unknowns" (together with the traded bond yields). Then the simulated "unknowns" together with the calibrated "knowns" derived from them determine the simulated calibrated zero coupon rate curves (which are mutually correlated). This simulation process can be carried out as many times as desired. Zero Coupon Rate Spread Series Modelled as a GBM
Here we need to assume not only that each standard maturity zero coupon rate spread (successive spread or spread over the base issuer) is "known" (that is, each zero coupon rate figuring in the spread (each leg, say) is "known") at at least one of the specified times t0 , tx , ... , tN (or, equivalently, at at least one of the specified trading dates), but also that each of these spread series has, at at least one of the specified times, each leg "unknown". Note that this is a stronger requirement than that each spread series be "unknown" at at least one of the specified times : we require that, at some time, each leg of the spread be "unknown". This new requirement can always be satisfied by adding, if need be, a new date (and associated time), at which all the zero coupon rates are necessarily "unknown", to the set of specified trading dates.
As before, we calculate the "known" standard maturity zero coupon rates and the "unknown" standard maturity zero coupon rates in turn until successive iterates for the "known" zero coupon rates are equal (that is, until convergence is reached). There are no changes to the method of calculation of the first iterate of the "known" zero coupon rates. There are no changes to the method of calculation of any of the iterates of the "unknown" zero coupon rates, given the "known" zero coupon rates. Suppose that we are to calculate a second or later iterate of the "known" zero coupon rates, given the current estimate of the "unknown" zero coupon rates and the traded bond yields for all issuers and all trading dates. So, at this stage, the "known" zero coupon rates have unknown values (are unknown) and the "unknown" zero coupon rates have known values (are known). As we showed above, we can express the calibration requirement, depending on the given traded yields, as a set of simultaneous equations whose unknown variables are the standard maturity zero coupon rates. But each standard maturity zero coupon rate is an affine function of standard maturity zero coupon rate spreads. So we have, in fact, a set of simultaneous equations whose unknown variables are the standard maturity zero coupon rate spreads. Now some of these spreads are known (that is, their values are determined by the "unknown" zero coupon rates) and the others are unknown (that is, their values are not determined by the "unknown" zero coupon rates). Thus we get a set of simultaneous equations whose unknown variables are the unknown spreads. But by our assumption above, each spread series has, at some trading date, each leg "unknown" (this is not equivalent to each spread series being "unknown" at some trading date). Thus each spread is known at some trading date.
Let us consider an unknown standard maturity zero coupon rate spread, say S k) (ni) for m e {1,..., βik) } . First suppose that k = 1 , so that the spread has one leg. Our assumption above means that we can choose some i = t ',,m)such that -xK(k,ι,m) and
Figure imgf000103_0002
= inf |t; -
Figure imgf000103_0001
df s ik , = j,^ _ χ^ _ Then we have
S (ni) = S (m) exp(s(k'l>m)A* (S, k, min(i, i), max(*, i), m)) . Note that the value of S^ (m) is known because S (m) = R^k) (ni) and R (ni) is
"unknown"
Figure imgf000103_0003
suppose that k > 1 , so that the spread has two legs.
Then S w (m) = R ) (m) — R k ) (m) for some k' . If we are modelling successive spreads, then k' = k - 1. If we are modelling spreads over a base issuer, then kf = 1.
Our assumption above means that we can choose some i = t ''''n)such that —ιK k,i,m) A—lK(k,,i,m) and
Figure imgf000103_0004
infft, -tl |— ιK(k, j,m) A — ,K(k', j,m)\. df
Put s ik'l'm ) = Z[l<l} ~ Z{t»} - Then we have
S (m) = Sf ω(m)exp(5 '''m)Δ*(S,fe,min(t',t),max(i,t),m)) . Note that the value of
Sf k) (ni) is known because
Figure imgf000103_0005
and Rf> (m) are both "unknown"
Figure imgf000103_0006
We can then replace each occurrence of an unknown spread in the simultaneous equations by an expression involving an unknown spread change of the form A* (S ,k,πήn(i,i),max(i,ι),m) . In fact, the left hand side of each equation becomes a differentiable function of such unknown spread changes. Then, by a process of iterative refinement of affine approximations similar to that used before for the calculation of the "unknown" zero coupon rates in the case of spread modelling, we can derive the expected values of the unknown spread changes. In this iteration, the left hand side of each calibration equation, as a function of the unknown spread changes figuring in the equation, is replaced by its affine approximation, and we add (to the conditioning) a linearised constraint for each calibration equation. These linearised constraints need to be recomputed at each step in the iteration. We have "vertical" constraints, corresponding to "runs" of spreads, which do not change from one iteration to another of the affine approximation loop. We also have "horizontal" constraints similar to those used in the calculation of "unknown" zero coupon rates from "known" zero coupon rates, except that here the role that the "known" zero coupon rates played is played by the "unknown" (known) zero coupon rates. Once these "horizontal" constraints are expressed in terms of unknown spread changes, they are non-linear and require affine approximations which need to be recomputed at each step in the iteration. Assuming convergence, we get the non-linear constraints satisfied exactly. Given the expected values of the unknown spread changes and the known spread values, determined by the "unknown" zero coupon rates, we can "back out" the unknown spreads. Then the unknown spreads and the known spreads determine the next iterate of the "known" zero coupon rate values which, together with the "unknown" zero coupon rate values, are calibrated with the traded yields. ,
Once the outer loop converges (that is, when successive iterates for the "known" zero coupon rates are equal), the "known" and "unknown" zero coupon rates together determine the calibrated standard maturity curves based on expected zero coupon rate changes.
To simulate calibrated zero coupon curves, we can simulate the "unknown" zero coupon rates, given the "known" zero coupon rates provided by the curves based on expected zero coupon rate changes. Then we can calibrate the "known" zero coupon rates as shown above, but using the simulated "unknown" zero coupon rates (together with the traded bond yields). Then the simulated "unknown" zero coupon rates together with the calibrated "known" zero coupon rates derived from them determine the simulated calibrated zero coupon rate curves. This simulation process can be carried out as many times as desired.
hi practice, we will need to make the additional assumption that, for any given issuer, maturity bucket and trading date, there is at most one traded bond of the given issuer whose trading date is the given trading date and whose maturity falls in the given maturity bucket. The reason for this assumption is, essentially, that one factor (the standard maturity zero coupon rate, at the given trading date, for the given issuer and maturity bucket) is, in general, inadequate to explain variation that may be multidimensional. This assumption is applicable both in the case where zero coupon rate series are modelled as a (G)BM and in the case where spread series are modelled as a GBM.
Mean Reversion
The stochastic differential equation for a one-dimensional mean-reverting Brownian Motion is X = (Xt)t≡R , is dXt ~ (μ ~ άXt)dt + σdWt , where μ is the long term average, per unit interval of time, of the process increments, a ≥ 0 is the speed of mean-reversion and σ ≥ 0 is the standard deviation, per unit interval of time, of the process increments, and W = (Wt) R is a standard Brownian Motion (mean zero, variance one). This generalises the notion of a Brownian Motion (take = 0 to get a Brownian Motion with mean μ and variance σ2 per unit interval of time). In the case
where > 0, — is called the level of mean reversion.
A one-dimensional mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion is a stochastic process of the form exp(X) where X - (Xt) R is a mean-reverting Brownian Motion.
This generalises the notion of a Geometric Brownian Motion. See Kloeden P., Platen E., Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential
Equations, Springer-Verlag, 1992, where the terminology used is normal mean- reverting process for mean-reverting Brownian Motion and lognormal mean-reverting process for mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion.
One can extend these notions to the case of several dimensions. Let X be a one-dimensional mean-reverting Brownian Motion. Given Xt , the value of X at time t, there are formulae for the mean and variance of X(+Δ( for Δt > 0. This requires the evaluation of stochastic integrals. One can show that the process increment Xt+At - Xt is normally distributed, conditional on the known value for Xt .
Then Xt+&t is also normally distributed, conditional on the known value for Xt . In the case of higher-dimensional mean-reverting Brownian Motions, one can show that given the vector of values of the processes at time t, the vector of process increments over the time interval [t, t + Δt] is multivariate normal.
Corresponding results can be shown for mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motions.
Suppose we have incomplete rate data, for a mean-reverting Brownian Motion in several dimensions, at several points in time. Suppose also that each rate is known at at least one point in time. We can choose one known rate, say, the first known, for each rate series. We can then calculate the multivariate normal distribution of the rate changes, for the several rate series and the time intervals determined by successive points in time, conditional on these known rates (exactly one per rate series). This distribution plays the role that the unconditional distribution of rate changes played earlier for non-mean-reverting Brownian Motions. We can then use all the incomplete rate data to determine known and unknown rate changes and calculate the multivariate normal distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values as we did before. We can then fill the unknown rates as we did before for non-mean-reverting Brownian Motions.
This analysis is easily adapted to mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motions and can be carried through to the application to modelling zero coupon rate curves. It is straight-forward to combine mean-reverting Brownian Motions and mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motions.
Unconditional Serial Correlation
We now show how the assumption of the existence of a Brownian Motion in several dimensions can be weakened to allow for unconditional serial correlation of rate changes. Note that the Brownian Motion assumption implies that rate changes in several dimensions are serially uncorrelated and, in fact, are serially independent. We suppose, as before, that we have several rate series, a number of specified points in time and a set of incomplete rate data and that each rate series has a known value at at least one of the specified points in time. We also suppose that we have, for each rate series, a specification of its parametric model type as normal or lognormal. These are both parametric probability distributions : a random variable is lognormally distributed if the natural logarithm of the random variable is normally distributed. This corresponds to our former specification of parametric model types (Brownian Motion/Geometric Brownian Motion) for the several rate series. If a rate series is specified as normal, then its rate changes are understood to be differences of rates. If a rate series is specified as be lognormal, then its rate changes are understood to be differences of natural logarithms of rates. We then suppose that the random vector of all rate changes over single time intervals is unconditionally multivariate normal, a single time interval being understood to mean a time interval determined by successive specified points in time, and that the parameters of the unconditional multivariate normal distribution are specified. This requires a specification of the unconditional mean for each rate change over a single time interval and a specification of the unconditional covariance for each pair of rate changes over single, possibly different, time intervals, or one could specify unconditional correlations and unconditional standard deviations and calculate the unconditional covariances. Then the rest of the analysis, including the application to modelling zero coupon rate curves, can be carried through except that any simplifications of formulae that were justified by the Brownian Motion assumption are not made if they are not justified by the weakened assumptions.
Industrial Applicability
The present invention provides commercial value in the field of financial modelling. It may be used to provide more accurate input rate data for the historical or Monte Carlo simulation of portfolio values and for the more accurate pricing (and hedging) of individual financial instruments or of portfolios of financial instruments. These applications are important to investment banks and other financial institutions for assessing the values of deals and trading portfolios and for measuring the risks arising out of deals and trading portfolios. More accurate methods of assessing value have direct effects on the profitability of trading activities. More accurate methods of measuring risk permit more effective management of risk and more efficient allocation of risk capital.
The present invention allows missing rates in historical rate series to be filled in a manner that is statistically consistent with observed rates. In a historical simulation, rate changes derived from filled historical rate series are used to simulate future values of trading portfolios which, in turn, are used to derive measures of the credit and market risk of the trading portfolios. More accurate methods of filling historical rate data lead to more accurate measures of risk.
Monte Carlo simulations of the credit or market risk of trading portfolios are normally based on complete sets of current rates. The present invention allows Monte Carlo simulations to be based on incomplete sets of recent rates. A further advantage of the present invention is that it allows the modelling of value and risk to be based on specific hypotheses or scenarios concerning the future levels of rates. This allows greater refinement in the so-called "stress testing" of portfolios where the impact of specific adverse rate scenarios on portfolio values is analysed.
The present invention may also be used for the more accurate pricing (and hedging) of financial instruments. Unobserved input rates required for pricing models may be estimated or simulated in a manner that takes account of other rates, possibly observed at other times. For example, to value an option of some given maturity that has not recently traded, the option's implied volatility may be estimated or simulated from the calculated implied volatilities of recently traded options (on the same asset) of possibly different maturities. Note that the implied volatility of a traded option is the volatility, over the life of the option, of the price of the underlying asset of the option which, when used as the input in an option pricing model, gives a fair value equal to observed market price of the option. Another possibility for valuing options and other types of derivative financial instruments is to use the conditional rate dynamics based on an incomplete set of recent rates to simulate contingent pay-offs. Simulated payoffs would allow the estimation of the expected value of a pay-off and this could be discounted to the present using the appropriate risk-free rate to provide a fair value. This approach would require a shift from the real world dynamics to risk-neutral dynamics.
The present invention also has potential application to time series other than the rate series of financial markets.
It will be appreciated by persons skilled in the art that many variations and/or modifications may be made to the invention as shown in the specific embodiments without departing from the spirit or scope of the invention as broadly described. The present embodiments are, therefore, to be considered in all respects as illustrative and not restrictive.
It is noted that the present invention can be expressed as a computer program or software to cause a computer to perform the method. The computer program can have data input means to receive the assumed unconditional dynamics or unconditional distribution, as appropriate, and the incomplete rate data or traded bond data, as appropriate. The computer program can have data output means to output the modelled values. The computer program can have a modelling engine to carry out the steps defined by the method.
It is also noted that use the term conditional zero coupon rate dynamics to denote the zero coupon rate dynamics implied by the unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and the traded bond data [specified bond trades.
Further, it is noted that in Australia, the base issuer may be chosen to be the Commonwealth of Australia. For each pair of issuers, the maturities of the specified zero coupon rate series for the two issuers can correspond.
In specifying the unconditional dynamics of the zero coupon rate spread series as Geometric Brownian Motion ensures that modelled zero coupon rate spreads are positive, which can accord with assumptions made about the relative credit quality of the issuers. For example, a constructed zero coupon rate curve may include maturity points corresponding to the maturities of the traded bonds whose issuers and trading dates are associated with the curve.
The term conditional zero coupon rate dynamics can be used to denote the zero coupon rate dynamics implied by the unconditional zero coupon rate spread dynamics and the traded bond data specified bond trades. For example, the step of populating the unknown rates with simulated values may be carried out by taking a random drawing from the multidimensional conditional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes and then inferring the simulated values from the random drawing of the unknown rate changes and the known rate values.
It is noted that rate dynamics is understood to mean a probabilistic model of how rate series change in value over time. Further, the term conditional rate dynamics denotes the rate dynamics implied by the unconditional rate dynamics and the known rate values.
The dimension of the problem solved in the present method grows quickly and geometrically as both the number of rate series and the number of specified times increase. Although the assumption of Brownian Motion or Geometric Brownian Motion implies that the rate changes in several dimensions are unconditionally serially independent, that does not mean that the rate changes in several dimensions are not conditionally serially dependent. The method of modelling may be viewed as an exercise in unravelling the nature of such multidimensional serial dependence.

Claims

THE CLAIMS DEFINING THE INVENTION ARE AS FOLLOWS:-
1. A computer-implemented method of modelling unknown values of several rate series at specified times, the several rate series having unconditional rate dynamics characterised by a parametric model type in several dimensions, each rate series having at least one known value, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional rate dynamics by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation and a mean of the rate change per unit interval of time, and for each pair of rate series assigning a correlation coefficient of the rate changes per unit interval of time; specifying a known or unknown rate value for each rate series and for each specified time; calculating the values of the known rate changes; calculating an unconditional multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes; and computing a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values.
2. A method according to claim 1 wherein the specified times are uniformly spaced.
3. A method according to claim 1 wherein the assigned standard deviations, means and correlation coefficients of the rate changes per unit interval of time are determined from historically observed rate values.
4. A method according to claim 1 wherein the parametric model type of each rate series is Brownian Motion or Geometric Brownian Motion, and the parametric model type of the several rate series together is Brownian Motion, Geometric Brownian Motion or a combination of the two.
5. A method according to claim 1 wherein further comprising the step of computing marginal probability distributions of the unknown rate values conditional on the known rates taking their known values.
6. A method according to claim 5 wherein the marginal probability distributions of the unknown rates are determined from the computed multidimensional conditional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes and from the known rate values.
7. A method according to claim 1 further comprising the step of populating the unknown rates with numerical values such that the rate changes arising out of the known rate values and the populated unknown rate values take their expected values conditional on the known rates taking their known values.
8. A method according to claim 1 further comprising the step of populating the unknown rates with their expected values conditional on the known rates taking their known values.
9. A method according to claim 1 further comprising the step of populating the unknown rates with simulated values being conditional on the known rates taking their known values.
10. A method according to claim 9 wherein populating simulated values are correlated consistently with the multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rates conditional on the known rates taking their known values.
11. A method according to any one of claims 7 to 10 wherein the steps of populating the unknown rates is effected using the conditional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes and the known rate values.
12. A method according to claim 11 wherein the step of populating the unknown rates with simulated values is effected by taking a random drawing from the multidimensional conditional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes and then deriving the simulated values from the random drawing of the unknown rate changes and the known rate values.
13. A method according to any one of the preceding claims wherein the specified unconditional rate dynamics does not depend on the known rate values.
14. A method according to claim 1 wherein the time underlying the assumed rate dynamics is calendar time, trading time or other preferred time system, wherein trading time is derived from calendar time by excising non-trading periods from the time continuum.
15. A method according to claim 14 wherein, when the time underlying the assumed rate dynamics is taken to be trading time, the length in trading days of each interval of calendar time is specified.
16. A method according to any one of claims 7 to 12 wherein the step of populating the unknown rates depends on all specified known values of all the rate series at all specified times.
17. A method according to claim 1 further comprising the step of simulating unknown values as a function of all known values of all rate series at all of the specified times.
18. A computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the issuers, the specified zero coupon rate series having unconditional dynamics characterised by a parametric model type in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of : specifying the unconditional dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series by assigning for each zero coupon rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon rate changes per unit interval of time, and assigning a correlation coefficient of the rate zero coupon changes per unit interval of time for each pair of zero coupon rate series; specifying the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series at the specified trading dates conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
19. A method according to claim 18 wherein the assigned standard deviations, means and correlation coefficients of the zero coupon rate changes per unit interval of time are determined from historically observed trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
20. A method according to claim 18 wherein the parametric model type of each specified zero coupon rate series is Brownian Motion or Geometric Brownian Motion, and the parametric model type of the several rate series together is Brownian Motion, Geometric Brownian Motion or a combination of the two.
21. A method according to claim 18 wherein the specified trading dates are uniformly spaced.
22. A method according to claim 18 wherein each of the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers is assigned a trading date, an issuer, a settlement date, a maturity date, a coupon rate, a coupon frequency and a traded yield.
23. A method according to claim 22 wherein, for each issuer and each specified trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds of the given issuer that traded on the given trading date are distinct.
24. A method according to claim 22 wherein, for each specified zero coupon rate series, there is a specified trading date such that for each zero coupon rate series in the given zero coupon series, a specified bond trade exists having an assigned trading date being the given trading date, and having an assigned issuer being that of the given zero coupon rate series and having an assigned maturity being close to that of the given zero coupon rate series.
25. A method according to any one of claims 18 to 24 further comprising the step of specifying, for each issuer, a bond pricing function and an interpolating function for zero coupon rates.
26. A method according to any one of claims 18 to 25 comprising the step of iteratively constructing, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, an expected value of a zero coupon rate curve conditional on the specified bond trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers, or constructing a zero coupon rate curve comprising zero coupon rates having values being substantially their modes conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
27. A method according to any one of claims 18 to 25 further comprising the step of constructing, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, a simulated zero coupon rate curve conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
28. A method according to claim 26 or 27 wherein a constructed expected or simulated zero coupon rate curve or a constructed zero coupon rate curve comprising zero coupon rates having values being substantially their conditional modes includes maturity points additional to the maturities of the specified zero coupon rate series of the issuer associated with the curve.
29. A method according to claim 28 wherein a constructed zero coupon rate curve includes maturity points corresponding to the maturities of the traded bonds having issuers and trading dates associated with the curve.
30. A method according to claim 18 wherein the specified unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics does not depend on trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
31. A method according to claim 18 wherein the time underlying the zero coupon rate dynamics is measured as calendar time or as trading time.
32. A method according to claim 31 such that when the time underlying the assumed rate dynamics is trading time, the length in trading days of each interval of calendar time is specified.
33. A method according to any one of claims 18 to 32 further comprising the step of modelling the specified zero coupon rate series for all issuers, at each specified trading date consistently with the specified unconditional zero coupon rate dynamics and with the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
34. A method according to claim 26 or 27 further comprising the steps of calibrating each constructed curve against the bond trades having issuers and trading dates being associated with the curve, and incorporating correlation effects arising out of trades in bonds of other issuers at other dates.
35. A method according to claim 26 or 27 further comprising the step of pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, bonds of the one or more issuers other than the specified traded bonds, and estimating or simulating values of portfolios of bonds of the one or more issuers at the specified trading dates consistently with the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
36. A computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the issuers, the number of specified zero coupon rate series of each issuer being equal and the zero coupon rate series determining zero coupon rate spread series having unconditional dynamics characterised by a parametric model type in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of : specifying the unconditional dynamics of the zero coupon rate spread series by assigning, for each zero coupon rate spread series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon rate spread changes per unit interval of time, and assigning a correlation coefficient of the zero coupon rate spread changes per unit interval of time for each pair of zero coupon rate spread series; specifying the trades of the one or more issuers; and calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the specified trades in the one or more issuers.
37. A method according to claim 36 wherein the assigned standard deviations, means and correlation coefficients of the zero coupon rate spread changes per unit interval of time are determined from historically observed trades in the one or more issuers.
38. A method according to claim 36 wherein the parametric model type of each zero coupon rate spread series is Geometric Brownian Motion or Brownian Motion, and the parametric model type of the several rate series together is Brownian Motion, Geometric Brownian Motion or a combination of the two.
39. A method according to claim 36 wherein one of the one or more bond issuers is specified as a base issuer having at all times a higher credit quality than that of the other issuers.
40. A method according to claim 36 wherein the determined zero coupon rate spread series comprise the specified zero coupon rate series for the base issuer and, for each of the one or more issuers other than the base issuer and for each specified zero coupon rate series for a specified issuer, the difference between the specified zero coupon rate series and the corresponding specified zero coupon rate series for the base issuer where the correspondence depends on the ordering of the zero coupon rate series by their associated maturities.
41. A method according to claim 36 wherein the one or more bond issuers are ordered in descending order of credit quality, and the zero coupon rate spread series comprise the specified zero coupon rate series for the base issuer and, for each issuer other than the base issuer and for each specified zero coupon rate series for the given issuer, the difference between the given zero coupon rate series and the corresponding specified zero coupon rate series for the previous issuer in the ordering of issuers by credit quality where the correspondence depends on the ordering of the zero coupon rate series by their associated maturities.
42. A method according to claim 36 wherein, for each issuer and each specified trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds of the given issuer that traded on the given trading date are distinct.
43. A method according to claim 36 wherein each specified trade in the bonds of the one or more issuers is assigned a trading date, an issuer, a settlement date, a maturity date, a coupon rate, a coupon frequency and a traded yield.
44. A method according to claim 36 further comprising the step of specifying a bond pricing function and an interpolation function for the zero coupon rates of the issuer for each of the one or more specified issuers.
45. A method according to claim 36 wherein, for each zero coupon rate spread series determined by the specified zero coupon rate series, there is a specified trading date such that for each zero coupon rate series in the given zero coupon spread series, a specified bond trade exists having an assigned trading date being the given trading date, and having an assigned issuer being that of the given zero coupon rate series and having an assigned maturity being close to that of the given zero coupon rate series.
46. A method according to any one of claims 36 to 45 further comprising the step of iteratively constructing, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, a zero coupon rate curve comprising zero coupon rates having values being substantially their modes conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
47. A method according to any one of claims 36 to 45 further comprising the step of constructing, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, a simulated zero coupon rate curve conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
48. A method according to claim 46 or 47 wherein a constructed expected or simulated zero coupon rate curve or a constructed zero coupon rate curve comprising zero coupon rates having values being substantially their conditional modes includes maturity points additional to the maturities of the specified zero coupon rate series of the issuer associated with the curve.
49. A method according to claim 36 wherein the unconditional zero coupon rate spread dynamics does not depend of the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
50. A method according to claim 36 wherein the time underlying the zero coupon rate dynamics and the zero coupon rate spread dynamics is measured as calendar time or as trading time.
51. A method according to claim 36 wherein the modelling of the specified zero coupon rate series for all issuers at the specified trading dates is consistent with the specified unconditional zero coupon rate spread dynamics and with the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
52. A method according to claim 36 wherein each constructed curve is calibrated against the bond trades having assigned issuers and trading dates being associated with the curve, and correlation effects arising out of trades in bonds of other issuers at other dates are incorporated.
53. A method according to claim 52 further comprising the step of pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, bonds of the one or more issuers other than the specified traded bonds and determining estimated or simulated values of portfolios of bonds of the one or more issuers at the specified trading dates according to the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
54. A computer-implemented method of modelling the unknown values of several rate series at specified times, the several rate series having unconditional rate dynamics being mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion or a combination of the two, in several dimensions, each rate series having at least one known value, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional rate dynamics by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation, a long-term average of the rate changes per unit interval of time, a speed of mean reversion, and assigning a correlation coefficient of the rate changes for each pair of rate series; specifying, for each rate series and each specified time, a known or unknown rate value; calculating the values of the known rate changes; selecting at least one known rate for each rate series; calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes conditional on the selected at least one known rate; and calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values using the multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes conditional on the selected at least one known rate.
55. A method according to claim 54 wherein the parametric model type of each rate series is a mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion.
56. A method according to claim 54 wherein the standard deviations, long-term averages, speeds of mean reversion and correlation coefficients are determined from historically observed rate values.
57. A method according to claim 54 further comprising the step of computing the marginal probability distributions of the unknown rate values conditional on the known rates taking their known values, wherein the marginal probability distributions are determined from the computed multidimensional conditional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes and from the known rate values.
58. A method according to claim 54 further comprising the step of populating the unknown rates with numerical values such that the rate changes arising out of the known rate values and the populated unknown rate values take their expected values conditional on the known rates taking their known values.
59. A method according to claim 54 further comprising the step of populating the unknown rates with their expected values conditional on the known rates taking their known values.
60. A method according to claim 54 further comprising the step of populating the unknown rates with simulated values conditional on the known rates taking their known values, wherein the simulated values are correlated consistently with the multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rates conditional on the known rates taking their known values.
61. A method according to any one of claims 58 to 60 wherein the steps of populating the unknown rates depends on the conditional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes and the known rate values.
62. A method according to claim 54 wherein the specified unconditional rate dynamics does not take depend on the known rate values.
63. A computer-implemented method modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the one or more issuers, the unconditional dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series being mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion, or a combination of the two, in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of: specifying unconditional dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series by assigning, for each zero coupon rate series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation, a long-term average of the rate changes per unit interval of time and a speed of mean reversion, and specifying for each pair of zero coupon rate series, a correlation coefficient of the rate changes; specifying trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; and calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
64. A method according to claim 63 wherein the parametric model type of each specified zero coupon rate series is mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion.
65. A method according to claim 63 wherein each of the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers is specified by assigning a trading date, an issuer, a settlement date, a maturity date, a coupon rate, a coupon frequency and a traded yield.
66. A method according to claim 65 wherein, for each issuer and each specified trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds of the given issuer that traded on the given trading date are distinct.
67. A method according to claim 63 wherein the iterative process constructs, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, an expected zero coupon rate curve conditional on the specified bond trades or a zero coupon rate curve comprising zero coupon rates being substantially their modes conditional on the specified bond trades.
68. A method according to claim 63 further comprising the step of constructing, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, a simulated zero coupon rate curve conditional on the specified bond trades.
69. A method according to claims 67 or 68 wherein a constructed expected or simulated zero coupon rate curve or a constructed zero coupon rate curve comprising zero coupon rates having values being substantially their conditional modes includes maturity points additional to the maturities of the specified zero coupon rate series of the issuer associated with the curve.
70. A method according to claim 63 further comprising the step of pricing, at any of the specified trading dates, bonds of the one or more issuers other than the specified traded bonds, and estimating or simulating the values of portfolios of bonds of the one or more issuers at the specified trading dates consistently with the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
71. A computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the issuers, the number of specified zero coupon rate series of each issuer being equal and the specified zero coupon rate series of the bond issuers determining zero coupon rate spread series, having unconditional dynamics characterised by mean-reverting Brownian Motion or mean-reverting Geometric Brownian Motion, or a combination of the two, in several dimensions, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional dynamics of the zero coupon rate spread series by assigning, for each zero coupon rate spread series, a parametric model type, a standard deviation, a long-term average of the rate spread changes per unit interval of time and a speed of mean reversion, and assigning for each pair of zero coupon rate spread series, the correlation coefficient of the zero coupon rate spread changes: specifying trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; calculating the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers iteratively.
72. A method according to claim 71 wherein each of the specified bond trades are specified by assigning a trading date, an issuer, a settlement date, a maturity date, a coupon rate, a coupon frequency and a traded yield.
73. A method according to claim 72 wherein, for each issuer and each specified trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds of the given issuer that traded on the given trading date are distinct.
74. A method according to claim 71 wherein the iterative process constructs, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, a zero coupon rate curve including zero coupon rates having values being substantially their modes conditional on the specified bond trades.
75. A method according to claim 71 further comprising the step of constructing for each issuer and for each specified trading date, a simulated zero coupon rate curve conditional on the specified bond trades.
76. A method according to claim 74 or 75 wherein a constructed zero coupon rate curve includes maturity points additional to the maturities of the specified zero coupon rate series of the issuer associated with the curve.
77. A computer-implemented method of modelling the unknown values of several rate series at specified times conditional on known values of the rate series, the rate series having unconditional rate changes that are multivariate normal and each rate series having at least one known value, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional distribution of the rate changes by assigning, for each rate series, a parametric model type and assigning, for each rate change over a time interval determined by successive specified times, a standard deviation and a mean of the rate changes and assigning, for each pair of rate changes over time intervals determined by successive specified points in time, a correlation coefficient of the rate changes; specifying, for each rate series and each specified times, the known or unknown rate value; calculating the values of the known rate changes; calculating an unconditional multidimensional probability distribution of the known and unknown rate changes; and calculating a multidimensional probability distribution of the unknown rate changes conditional on the known rate changes taking their known values.
78. A method according to claim 77 wherein the parametric model type of each rate series is normal or lognormal and the standard deviations, means and correlation coefficients are determined from historically observed rate values.
79. A computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the one or more issuers, the changes in the specified zero coupon rate series having unconditional distribution that is multivariate normal, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional distribution of the rate changes by assigning, for each specified zero coupon rate series, a parametric model type and assigning for each rate change over a time interval determined by successive specified times, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon rate changes, and specifying, for each pair of rate changes over time intervals determined by successive specified times, a correlation coefficient of the zero coupon rate changes; specifying trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers.
80. A method according to claim 79 wherein each of the bond trades of the one or more issuers is specified by assigning a trading date, an issuer, a settlement date, a maturity date, a coupon rate, a coupon frequency and a traded yield.
81. A method according to claim 79 wherein the iterative process constructs, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, an expected value of a zero coupon rate curve conditional on the specified bond trades or a zero coupon rate curve comprising zero coupon rates having values substantially their modes conditional on the specified bond trades.
82. A method according to claim 79 further comprising the step of constructing, for each issuer and for each specified trading date, a simulated zero coupon rate curve conditional on the specified bond trades.
83. A method according to claim 81 or 82 wherein a constructed expected or simulated zero coupon rate curve or a constructed zero coupon rate curve comprising zero coupon rates having values being substantially their conditional modes zero coupon rate curve includes maturity points additional to the maturities of the specified zero coupon rate series of the issuer associated with the curve.
84. A computer-implemented method of modelling the dynamics of specified zero coupon rate series of one or more bond issuers at specified trading dates conditional on specified trades in bonds of the issuers, the number of specified zero coupon rate series of each issuer being equal and the zero coupon rate series of the bond issuers determining zero coupon rate spread series wherein changes over time in the spread series have an unconditional distribution being multivariate normal, the method comprising the steps of: specifying the unconditional distribution of the zero coupon spread rate changes by assigning, for each zero coupon spread rate series, a parametric model type, by specifying, for each zero coupon spread rate change over a time interval determined by successive specified times, a standard deviation and a mean of the zero coupon spread rate changes, and by specifying, for each pair of zero coupon rate spread changes over time intervals determined by successive specified times, a correlation coefficient of the zero coupon spread rate changes; specifying the trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers; and calculating iteratively the dynamics of the specified zero coupon rate series at the specified trading dates conditional on the specified trades in the bonds of the one or more issuers iteratively.
85. A method according to claim 84 wherein one of the one or more bond issuers is specified as a base bond issuer having at all times a higher credit quality than that of the other bond issuers.
86. A method according to claim 84 wherein the determined zero coupon rate spread series comprise the specified zero coupon rate series for the base issuer and, for each for each issuer other than the base issuer and for each specified zero coupon rate series for the given issuer, the difference between the specified zero coupon rate series and the corresponding specified zero coupon rate series for the base issuer where the correspondence depends on the ordering of the zero coupon rate series by their associated maturities.
87. A method according to claim 84 wherein the one or more bond issuers are ordered in descending order of credit quality, and the determined zero coupon rate spread series comprise the specified zero coupon rate series for the base issuer and, for each issuer, other than the base issuer and for each specified zero coupon rate series for the given issuer, the difference between the given zero coupon rate series and the corresponding specified zero coupon rate series for the previous issuer in the ordering of issuers by credit quality where the correspondence depends on the ordering of the zero coupon rate series by their associated maturities.
88. A method according to claim 84 wherein, for each issuer and each specified trading date, the maturities of the traded bonds of the given issuer that traded on the given trading date are distinct.
89. A method according to claim 84 wherein for each zero coupon rate spread series determined by the specified zero coupon rate series, there is a specified trading date such that, for each zero coupon rate series in the given zero coupon spread series, a specified bond trade exists having an assigned trading date being the given trading date and having an assigned issuer being that of the given zero coupon rate series and having an assigned maturity being close to that of the given zero coupon rate series.
90. A computer-implemented method of detecting the known values, of several rate series at specified times, that are extreme, the method comprising the steps of: assigning a known or unknown rate value for each rate series and for each specified time; specifying a subset of the known rates comprising those that are to be accepted without question; specifying a confidence level and constructing, for each known rate that is not to be accepted without question and for each subset of the known rates that does not include the given known rate and that includes the known rates that are to be accepted without question, a confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, for the given rate conditional on the rates belonging to the given subset taking their known values; and iteratively constructing a subset of the known rates that are not to be accepted without question such that, for each rate belonging to the subset, the value of the rate does not lie within the confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, constructed for the rate conditional on the known rates which do not belong to the subset taking their known values, and for each known rate that does not belong to the subset and that is not to be accepted without question, the value of the rate lies within the confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, constructed for the rate conditional on the known rates, with the exception of the given known rate, which do not belong to the subset taking their known values.
91. A method according to claim 90 wherein the rate values are known for all rate series and for all specified times.
92. A method according to claim 90 wherein the subset of the known rates comprising those that are to be accepted without question is chosen to be empty.
93. A method of constructing, for each known rate that is not to be accepted without question and for each subset of the known rates that includes the known rates that are to be accepted without question and does not include the given rate, a confidence interval, based on the given confidence level, for the given rate conditional on the rates belonging to the given subset taking their known values, the construction of the confidence interval relying on the marginal probability distribution of the rate according to any one of claims 1, 54 and
PCT/AU2004/000770 2003-06-10 2004-06-10 Conditional rate modelling WO2004109566A1 (en)

Priority Applications (3)

Application Number Priority Date Filing Date Title
AU2004246035A AU2004246035C1 (en) 2003-06-10 2004-06-10 Conditional rate modelling
GB0600407A GB2419204A (en) 2003-06-10 2004-06-10 Conditional rate modelling
US11/297,476 US7979330B2 (en) 2003-06-10 2005-12-09 Conditional rate modelling

Applications Claiming Priority (2)

Application Number Priority Date Filing Date Title
AU2003902883 2003-06-10
AU2003902883A AU2003902883A0 (en) 2003-06-10 2003-06-10 Conditional rate modelling

Related Child Applications (1)

Application Number Title Priority Date Filing Date
US11/297,476 Continuation US7979330B2 (en) 2003-06-10 2005-12-09 Conditional rate modelling

Publications (1)

Publication Number Publication Date
WO2004109566A1 true WO2004109566A1 (en) 2004-12-16

Family

ID=31953924

Family Applications (1)

Application Number Title Priority Date Filing Date
PCT/AU2004/000770 WO2004109566A1 (en) 2003-06-10 2004-06-10 Conditional rate modelling

Country Status (4)

Country Link
US (1) US7979330B2 (en)
AU (1) AU2003902883A0 (en)
GB (1) GB2419204A (en)
WO (1) WO2004109566A1 (en)

Families Citing this family (8)

* Cited by examiner, † Cited by third party
Publication number Priority date Publication date Assignee Title
US7882022B2 (en) * 2003-06-13 2011-02-01 Peter K. Trzyna Computer support for mortgage lock option
US20130110703A9 (en) * 2003-06-13 2013-05-02 Greg H. Crocker Loan lock options
US20120158573A1 (en) * 2003-06-13 2012-06-21 Peter K. Trzyna Computer system to produce and communicate output data to carry out a financial transaction comprising a mortgage loan
US7689494B2 (en) * 2006-03-23 2010-03-30 Advisor Software Inc. Simulation of portfolios and risk budget analysis
US20110295767A1 (en) * 2010-05-27 2011-12-01 Sylvain Rock Raynes Inverse solution for structured finance
US8370245B2 (en) * 2010-08-20 2013-02-05 Nicholas Langdon Gunther Electronic information and analysis system
TWI708197B (en) * 2019-04-26 2020-10-21 國立成功大學 Predictive maintenance method for component of production tool and computer program product thereof
CN111368259B (en) * 2020-03-09 2023-05-12 南方电网科学研究院有限责任公司 Distribution network voltage data missing filling method and related device

Citations (4)

* Cited by examiner, † Cited by third party
Publication number Priority date Publication date Assignee Title
US5761386A (en) * 1996-04-05 1998-06-02 Nec Research Institute, Inc. Method and apparatus for foreign exchange rate time series prediction and classification
US5812988A (en) * 1993-12-06 1998-09-22 Investments Analytic, Inc. Method and system for jointly estimating cash flows, simulated returns, risk measures and present values for a plurality of assets
US6381554B1 (en) * 1997-09-02 2002-04-30 Nks Co., Ltd. Method of prediction time-series continuous data and a control method using the prediction method
US20030014356A1 (en) * 2001-06-29 2003-01-16 Sid Browne Method and system for simulating risk factors in parametric models using risk neutral historical bootstrapping

Family Cites Families (3)

* Cited by examiner, † Cited by third party
Publication number Priority date Publication date Assignee Title
US6343272B1 (en) * 1994-01-21 2002-01-29 Fdi/Genesis System for analyzing and managing equity participation life insurance and annuity contracts
CA2290888A1 (en) * 1999-11-26 2001-05-26 Algorithmics International Corp. Risk management, pricing and portfolio makeup system and method
US7590581B1 (en) * 2003-06-16 2009-09-15 Genesis Financial Products, Inc. Computer based system for pricing an index-offset deposit product

Patent Citations (4)

* Cited by examiner, † Cited by third party
Publication number Priority date Publication date Assignee Title
US5812988A (en) * 1993-12-06 1998-09-22 Investments Analytic, Inc. Method and system for jointly estimating cash flows, simulated returns, risk measures and present values for a plurality of assets
US5761386A (en) * 1996-04-05 1998-06-02 Nec Research Institute, Inc. Method and apparatus for foreign exchange rate time series prediction and classification
US6381554B1 (en) * 1997-09-02 2002-04-30 Nks Co., Ltd. Method of prediction time-series continuous data and a control method using the prediction method
US20030014356A1 (en) * 2001-06-29 2003-01-16 Sid Browne Method and system for simulating risk factors in parametric models using risk neutral historical bootstrapping

Also Published As

Publication number Publication date
AU2003902883A0 (en) 2003-06-26
GB2419204A (en) 2006-04-19
GB0600407D0 (en) 2006-02-15
US7979330B2 (en) 2011-07-12
US20060095292A1 (en) 2006-05-04

Similar Documents

Publication Publication Date Title
US7149715B2 (en) Method and system for simulating implied volatility surfaces for use in option pricing simulations
US20110173137A1 (en) Method and System for Stress Testing Simulations of the Behavior of Financial Instruments
US20120016810A1 (en) Method and system for simulating implied volatility surface for basket option pricing
US7979330B2 (en) Conditional rate modelling
US20030014356A1 (en) Method and system for simulating risk factors in parametric models using risk neutral historical bootstrapping
Rutkowski et al. Regulatory capital modeling for credit risk
Shevchenko et al. Loss distribution approach for operational risk capital modelling under Basel II: combining different data sources for risk estimation
Infanger Dynamic asset allocation strategies using a stochastic dynamic programming aproach
WO2005029373A2 (en) System and method for performing risk analysis
Wilmott et al. Uncertain parameters, an empirical stochastic volatility model and confidence limits
Dong et al. Risk margin quantile function via parametric and non-parametric bayesian approaches
Giordano et al. Real-world and risk-neutral probabilities in the regulation on the transparency of structured products
Felpel et al. Effective stochastic volatility: applications to ZABR-type models
Marti et al. Stress testing via contamination
Poudyal et al. Method of winsorized moments for robust fitting of truncated and censored lognormal distributions
US20130031026A1 (en) Methods and systems for valuating financial contracts involving early exercise
JP2003108753A (en) Risk management system of banking facility and processing method using the same
Zelvyte et al. Bayesian backtesting for counterparty risk models
AU2004246035B2 (en) Conditional rate modelling
Crispin Error propagation and attribution in simulation-based capital models
Yu et al. Semiparametric estimation for a class of time-inhomogeneous diffusion processes
Castor et al. Estimation of Probability of Default in Low Default Portfolios
Kappen et al. Simulation of Future Initial Margin along Low-Dimensional State Spaces
Li et al. A Robust Approach to the Interest Rate Term Structure Estimation
Fontana et al. Measuring distribution risk in discrete models

Legal Events

Date Code Title Description
AK Designated states

Kind code of ref document: A1

Designated state(s): AE AG AL AM AT AU AZ BA BB BG BR BW BY BZ CA CH CN CO CR CU CZ DE DK DM DZ EC EE EG ES FI GB GD GE GH GM HR HU ID IL IN IS JP KE KG KP KR KZ LC LK LR LS LT LU LV MA MD MG MK MN MW MX MZ NA NI NO NZ OM PG PH PL PT RO RU SC SD SE SG SK SL SY TJ TM TN TR TT TZ UA UG US UZ VC VN YU ZA ZM ZW

AL Designated countries for regional patents

Kind code of ref document: A1

Designated state(s): BW GH GM KE LS MW MZ NA SD SL SZ TZ UG ZM ZW AM AZ BY KG KZ MD RU TJ TM AT BE BG CH CY CZ DE DK EE ES FI FR GB GR HU IE IT LU MC NL PL PT RO SE SI SK TR BF BJ CF CG CI CM GA GN GQ GW ML MR NE SN TD TG

121 Ep: the epo has been informed by wipo that ep was designated in this application
WWE Wipo information: entry into national phase

Ref document number: 11297476

Country of ref document: US

WWE Wipo information: entry into national phase

Ref document number: 2004246035

Country of ref document: AU

WWE Wipo information: entry into national phase

Ref document number: 0600407.1

Country of ref document: GB

Ref document number: 0600407

Country of ref document: GB

ENP Entry into the national phase

Ref document number: 2004246035

Country of ref document: AU

Date of ref document: 20040610

Kind code of ref document: A

WWP Wipo information: published in national office

Ref document number: 2004246035

Country of ref document: AU

WWP Wipo information: published in national office

Ref document number: 11297476

Country of ref document: US

122 Ep: pct application non-entry in european phase